Gladwell brings up a study carried out by the RAND
Corporation in the 70s, which randomly assigned families to
health plans with varying levels of deductibles. Gladwell
writes, "As you might expect, the more that people were
asked to chip in for their health care the less care they
used. The problem was that they cut back equally on both
frivolous care and useful care." Dr. David Gratzer, a
Toronto physician and the author of Code Blue: Reviving
Canada's Health Care System, has a different take on
that same study. In
a 1997 article on the Canadian and U.S. Health care systems, he
writes that the study concluded that "free health care
results in costs 40% higher than systems with user fees
but practically no change in health outcomes." Maybe the
jury is still out on this one.
Gladwell is not only denying that
moral hazard makes people wastefully overconsume health
care. He himself is concerned with the exact opposite
problem: the plight of the uninsured, who are at risk of
getting too little health care, not too much. He peppers his
article with anecdotes of sorry individuals whose teeth have
rotted out, and one guy whose broken hand bone was never
fixed. These stories are disturbing, but they merely point
to a problem, not to a solution.
It is true that some
Americans have few options: the working poor are sometimes
not poor enough to qualify for subsidized health insurance
but not wealthy enough to afford private insurance. In
giving short shrift to HSAs, though, Gladwell dismisses a
tool that could help address this very problem, because if
HSAs can in fact help rein in soaring costs without
compromising quality (and maybe even improving it), that
will make health insurance less expensive, which would be
especially good for the working poor.
To be fair, Gladwell does
give an accurate description of the way HSAs work
high-deductible insurance for catastrophic events combined
with tax-free savings accounts for routine health care costs
but the discussion that follows leaves a lot to be
desired. He focuses on the distinction between social
insurance (in which the healthy and the sick pay roughly the
same amount) and actuarial insurance (in which those who
engage in riskier behaviour or have a pre-existing medical
condition will pay more). HSAs "represent the final,
irrevocable step in the actuarial direction," he writes
dramatically, but while HSAs may be actuarial, this is
hardly their defining characteristic.
Worse, Gladwell writes
that Americans with Medicare (a social-insurance model) are
getting "the security of being insulated against the
financial shock of serious illness." This is seriously
misleading, for it implies that people with private
insurance are not being insulated against that very same
shock.
The purpose of insurance is to spread risk around. Gladwell
writes that the basic question we should be asking ourselves
is "Do you think that this kind of redistribution of risk is
a good idea?" but this question is beside the point. Of
course it's a good idea, which is why HSAs apply only to
routine costs, with the high-deductible insurance continuing
to spread risk, just like every form of insurance. What
makes HSAs different is that they make explicit the
difference between routine and risky behaviour. There is no
such thing as the risk of having to get one's teeth cleaned.
Insurance that claims to redistribute this "risk" is not
insurance; it is simply income redistribution that dares not
speak its name. To fight against HSAs is to fight to
preserve this income redistribution, which is a position
Gladwell and others are free to defend, but to do so in the
name of preserving risk redistribution is a logical
fallacy known as a "bait and switch," and it is either
disingenuous or seriously confused.
There are so many options
one can consider when thinking about health care systems:
funding (paid for by taxpayers, employers, or individuals);
deductibles (zero, low or high); coverage (including routine
costs or limited to actual risks); social-insurance model or
actuarial model. In his enthusiasm for universally
taxpayer-funded, zero-deductible, cover-every-routine-cost,
everyone-pays-the-same health insurance, Gladwell has made
it harder, not easier, for us to clarify the various aspects
of the debate.
Why Not Try Freedom Instead? |
HSAs might help control costs and raise quality, but even
Dr. Gratzer, who thinks they're a good idea, doesn't think
they can do it alone. Writing in the Spring 2005 issue of
The Public Interest (see "What
ails health care"), he points out that while Americans
think of health care as largely untouched by government, "In
fact, the opposite is true health care is riddled with
laws and regulations that govern financing, billing, and
basic practice." It is in fact the laws in some states
mandating extravagant options (like acupuncture) and
forbidding interstate competition that make health insurance
prohibitively expensive for many Americans. In its own way,
the American health care industry is almost as paternalistic
as its Canadian counterpart, with predictably poor results.
Instead of trying to
decide here and now whether HSAs are a good idea, why not
allow them to compete with other forms of insurance in the
open market? If one is clearly better than the others, it
should be easy to convince people to choose it. If it is not
clear, some will choose one and some another and a great
market experiment will tell us the answer soon enough. But
this is just what a single, monolithic,
government-controlled monopoly does not allow: innovation,
competition, the rewarding of good ideas.
In fact, Malcolm Gladwell
specifically warns against the dire consequences of "making"
people choose insurance plans that suit their needs: the
sick will end up paying more than the healthy. "The days
when the healthy twenty-five-year-old subsidizes the
sixty-year-old with heart disease or diabetes are coming to
an end," he predicts ominously. At least in this sentence,
it is clear that the redistribution of risk is not what is
being advocated.
It is no small wonder
that Gladwell dislikes the current American health care
system. It's a mess. But he wants to hand over the whole
damn industry to the very people responsible for messing it
up. As usual, government intervention has caused problems
that beget more government intervention. Instead of invoking
the power of government to enforce one single vision of how
things should work, let's give people back the power of
choice, and see what rises to the top.
|