What is
a rate of interest if it is not a signal of the time-value
people place upon money? Accordingly, on what possible basis
can central bankers possess knowledge about these subjective
valuations that is superior to that of borrowers and lenders?
Interestingly, central bankers explicitly and repeatedly
disclaim any particular or superior knowledge about the
market-clearing price of petrol or, indeed, of other
producer or consumer goods. Conveniently, given the asset
bubbles they have repeatedly inflated, they also disavow any
ability to detect asset price bubbles in advance or even
after the fact! "Moreover," says Dr. Bernanke, "if a bubble
does exist, there is no guarantee that an attempt to 'pop' it
won't lead to violent and undesired adjustments in both
markets and the economy." So targeting the price level of
financial assets is a no-no because the central bank has
no special aptitude for it, and because these targets may lead
to various upsets. But targeting the price level of
producer and consumer goods is core business: "the central
bank should focus the use of its single macroeconomic
instrument, the short-term interest rate, on price and output
stability."
Astonishingly, however,
nobody (and certainly none among their cheer squad) laughs at
this contention. And nobody, it seems, states the blindingly
obvious: no matter how intelligent and diligent the central
banker, and no matter how good his administrative support, no
single person or Board of Governors, etc., can know better
than the many actors in markets the present and future prices
of assets, goods and services including the appropriate
price, tonight, tomorrow and every day thereafter, of
overnight loans among major banks. To acknowledge this
limitation and simultaneously to plead on central banks'
behalf is thus implicitly to admit that they will routinely
fix a rate of interest that does not tell the truth about
time.
Alas, virtually nobody
draws this conclusion. As a result, most market participants
allow central bankers to bamboozle them indeed, the former
seem to demand that the latter pull the wool over their eyes.
These days, most people are readily susceptible to the fallacy
that the employees of certain organisations possess vastly
more or better information, or systematically clearer crystal
balls, than everybody else. Central bankers also succumb to
this fallacy. Because they tend to be straight-A students and
Ivy League or Oxbridge graduates, these "insiders" are
vulnerable not just to the applause of market participants but
also to their own hubris. Behind closed doors, some of the
best and the brightest believe that the world is theirs to
command. And therein lies a great danger.
Central bankers seem
sincerely to think that they can comprehend the economic world
and its complexities. In particular, they believe they can
master it because their training tells them that they can
model and measure it. This, given the subjective nature of
economic calculation and the sometimes-arbitrary nature of
statistical sampling and compilation, is (to put it mildly) a
very ambitious belief. I do not dispute that Ivy League and
Oxbridge graduates can (and often do) deploy outstanding
brainpower in certain fields. I don't doubt that their brains
are better than mine. Nor do I criticise them because they
regularly fix what in retrospect is clearly a wrong rate. I
censure them because and despite all the logic and evidence
to the contrary they continuously presume to know what the
"appropriate" (they usually call it the "neutral") rate is.
Although they might cross
central bankers' minds, the central precepts of Austrian
School economics never ever pass their lips. They never
concede that under specific but widely feasible circumstances,
buyers and sellers in markets for goods and services act
remarkably intelligently; and central bankers never admit that
the transactions market participants undertake, as reflected
by prices in unfettered markets, are almost invariably more
sensible than those of the most intelligent individuals
including central bankers. Mark this point and mark it well:
even if no market participants have formidable SAT scores,
outstanding university credentials, etc. indeed, no matter
how "dumb" or "naοve" individual buyers and sellers might
allegedly be under a wide variety of conditions market
participants as a whole will make better decisions than
price-fixers and economic dictators.
Three Conclusions for Value Investors |
1. Central Bankers Are Bureaucrats
Look past their academic
credentials, awards and adulation, and recognise that central
bankers are simply glorified bureaucrats. A noble few
bureaucrats are indeed formidably intelligent and admirably
diligent; but the vast majority, submitting to institutional
imperatives, decline to display these characteristics. Great
or small, bureaucrats' major source of income is a government
paycheque; and in that respect they are no different from
struggling pensioners. To remember that central bankers are
government workers is to realise that they have particular
incentives and disincentives, that they routinely make
mistakes and, like all people, will devise extraordinarily
clever strategies to draw attention to their "successes" and
distract notice from their failures. Remind yourself
regularly: what on earth can government workers, who routinely
miscalculate and suffer no financial penalty when they do,
know about the future course of producer prices, consumer
prices and credit? Your answer should curb your enthusiasm for
their soothing words and the low rates (and therefore high
asset prices) they strive to deliver.
2. Bureaucrats' Reputations Will Fluctuate
Today, Alan Greenspan is
revered. The Fed is trading, figuratively, at a lofty multiple
of its "earnings." It also commands a sharp premium to its
book value and it pays no dividend. Market participants trust
it so emphatically that it need not bother to pay a stream of
tangible income: unrealised capital gains will do. But a
quarter of a century ago a diametrically different situation
prevailed. Paul Volcker, who had just commenced a long
campaign to restrain the CPI, enjoyed no such lofty
reputation. Nor did the institution he headed. In those days,
the Fed "traded" at a single-digit multiple, below its
metaphorical book value and at an allegorical double-digit
dividend yield (which matched Treasury yields at the time).
Many people doubted Mr. Volcker, others reviled him, and the
Fed was widely regarded as either impotent or incompetent (and
probably both).
But many shall be
restored that were once fallen. Interestingly, in recent years
the stock of the Volcker Fed has risen. According to Abby
Joseph Cohen (The Australian Financial Review, 26
October), "when history is written about the Fed, I think Paul
Volcker will get much more credit than he gets now. He was
facing a horrible situation with rampant inflation, and that's
not taking anything away from Mr. Greenspan, but Mr. Volcker
was a true hero." What does this resurrection imply for Dr.
Greenspan's reputation? The omens are not positive: many shall
fall that are now in honour. According to James Grant (The
New York Times, 31 October), "home with his wife watching
CNBC, the retired chairman may see strange and troubling
occurrences: rising interest rates, a falling dollar, a bear
market in residential real estate, a rising gold price. And
though tempted to interpret these disturbances as the markets'
expression of loss at his exit (he is, of course, only human),
Greenspan on reflection may finally see the truth. He was, in
fact, no oracle, after all."
3. Investors Reap What Bureaucrats Sow
The principal risk that
inheres in financial markets is not a crisis-induced loss of
confidence. Instead, it is miscalculation borne of earlier
overconfidence. The boldness and even recklessness among
market participants that today's crop of central bankers has
encouraged, and the artificiality of what these bureaucrats
have created, is their unwholesome legacy to their successors.
Part of this legacy is thus the possibility of speculative
upset, of disgust with financial assets and a long overdue
loss of faith in central bankers' stewardship of financial
markets. Value investors should look forward to that day.
As they buttress their
fortifications, investors might hope that Dr. Bernanke and his
colleagues really are as intelligent as advertised. In an
interview with the Minneapolis Fed in 2004, Bernanke
reflected "economics is a very difficult subject. I've
compared it to trying to learn how to repair a car when the
engine is running. The economy is always changing, our
knowledge of it is very incomplete, and our ability to predict
it is not impressive." These are surely among the wisest words
he has ever spoken. If he adheres to them, then investors can
rejoice because he will have to abandon any pretence of
anticipatory and aggressively inflationary monetary policy.
Alas, his next two
sentences dispel any such illusion. They tell us all we need
to know about the incoming Fed chairman and about
contemporary central bankers and their cheer squad more
generally and thus provide ample cause for concern:
"Nevertheless, I think that having good data, good statistics
and the United States generally has better macroeconomic
statistics than most countries and having good economists to
interpret those data and present the policy alternatives, has
a substantially beneficial effect on policymaking in the
United States, not only in monetary policy but in other areas
as well. I think in the end good economic policy research
makes a very big difference to the welfare of the average
person." So be on your guard: they're from the central bank
and, like social workers, are allegedly here to help us. In
self-defence, let us pray that events specifically, the
long-delayed consequences of his predecessor's policies
control Bernanke. Let us also hope that these events render
him more "Volcker" than "Greenspan."
|