Turgot blamed much of the economic decline of Limoges on
high taxation of the peasants there. Therefore, he wanted to
make taxation more equitably based. The taille was
based upon the tax collector's personal estimate of a
person's ability to pay – many aristocrats and clergy were
exempt from this tax leaving the tax burden on the peasants.
Unfortunately, Turgot was unable to abolish the taille.
However, he was able to eradicate the corvée which
consisted of unpaid forced labor on the royal roads. He was
able to replace this forced labor obligation with the paid
labor of proper workers, engineers, and contractors who
built and improved roads and drainage.
Serving as intendant of
the district of Limoges from 1761-1774, Turgot was able to
turn Limoges into one of the more prosperous districts in
France. During this time period, he was able to do much more
than to eliminate compulsory labor for public work. He took
many additional measures to save Limoges from widespread
famine. Among the many problems he faced there were: the
unequal incidence of the tax burden, unproductive
agriculture, scarcity, sporadic famine, restricted markets,
inadequate poor relief, poor roads, problems in transporting
troops, inadequate schools, inefficient gathering of
statistics, and so on.
Turgot introduced new
crops and new agricultural methods for cultivation and
storage. In addition, he established agricultural and
veterinary schools as a way to improve the quality of labor
in the district. He also reduced tariffs, promoted local
free trade, especially in corn, and used government funds in
the form of loans to grain markets in order to promote
imports into Limoges. Furthermore, Turgot instituted a
better relief system for the poor. Not only did he provide
work for the poor, he also reduced their taxes, established
emergency burdens on the rich, and placed special
restrictions on landowners.
In 1766 Turgot drew up a
list of questions on economics for two Chinese students whom
the Jesuits had sent to study in Paris. To help instruct
them in understanding his interrogations, he put his ideas
on paper. These 53 pages became his Reflections on the
Foundations and Distribution of Riches and included the
following themes: the division of labor, the origin and use
of money, the improvement of agriculture, the nature of
capital and the different modes of its employment, the
legitimacy of interest and loans, and revenue from land.
Then, in 1769, he wrote Value and Money which
developed an Austrian type theory beginning with Crusoe
economics and moving to two person exchange, to four person
exchange, and finally to a competitive market economy.
Turgot had a second
opportunity to put free market reforms into practice when he
served as France's Minister of Finance from 1774-1776. He
courageously attempted to save the French monarchy from
economic disaster by keeping government spending in check
and by encouraging private economic enterprise. Turgot
sought a lessening of state activity in many areas. The
French government had been running a deficit for years and
was close to bankruptcy as a type of welfare state for
various privileged and entrenched interests that obstructed
change. He wanted to return the country to solvency by
reducing expenditures and increasing tax revenue. Turgot
expected free markets to bring about increased production
leading to lower prices for consumers and to a greater
source of tax revenue for the state. He told Louis XVI to
cut government spending and to make taxes more equitable or
there would be a danger of revolution. As
Comptroller-General, Turgot adopted the slogan "No
Bankruptcy, No Increase in Taxes, No Loans."
Turgot was concerned with
failure in various markets including those in corn, labor,
and land rents. He also observed administrative chaos and
the proliferation of self-serving local authorities in the
form of bureaus, agencies, boards, courts, and councils.
There was also rampant corruption among government
officials. In addition, he saw the need for practical
political education of France's citizens. Turgot also looked
disapprovingly upon the guild system, a carryover from
medieval times, which prevented workers from entering
certain occupations without permission much like
contemporary occupational licensing.
To a great extent, as
Finance Minister, Turgot tried to institute on a larger
scale the reforms he introduced at Limoges. His highest
priority was to establish freedom of the grain industry in
all of France as he had done in Limoges. He said that
maintaining free trade in corn is the best way to prevent
scarcity in European nations. Turgot opposed strongly
government intervention in the corn trade. During 1775 he
attempted to reform the taille – a tax abuse that
weighed more heavily on the poor. In 1775, he was able to
gain enough support to have the controls lifted on the
internal trade of grain thus restoring the free circulation
of grains sold within France. He also wanted to abolish laws
restricting the wine industry. The next year Turgot, in one
of his Six Edicts of 1776, officially removed the controls
on the prices and transportation of grain, flour, and bread.
It was with these Six Edicts that he attempted to transform
and refashion the traditional monarchy of France.
A second of these edicts
called for the eventual abolition of guilds which
monopolized various trades. There remained only a few
exceptions. Turgot viewed work as a creative act and as a
key instrument of freedom. To shackle work with restrictions
was to violate the right to liberty and to stifle the
possibility of change. The guild system involved the use of
close corporations which represented the various trades – no
one could exercise such trades without going through a long
list of formalities. Turgot insisted that these corporations
be suppressed except in a few industries.
In another important
edict Turgot abolished the corvée thus furthering the
freedom of work. He ended the government's policy of
conscripting labor yearly to construct and maintain roads
and replaced it with a more efficient tax in money. It had
been the practice of the royal department of roads and
buildings to conscript the labor of peasants and farm
workers, without the payment of wages, in building and
repairing the royal highways. Turgot intended, in place of
the corvée, to employ a trained road-building force
and to pay their wages through a moderate tax increase. Road
construction and repair, along with the transportation of
military stores, were to be transferred to the supervision
of proper engineers. In addition, France was to have
transportation of military provisions well-guarded.
The last three of the six
Edicts were of little consequence and dealt with the
discharge of government officials who imposed restrictions
on ports and docks, abolishing tax on the cattle and meat
industries and cutting the tax on suet (i.e., hard animal
fat). Unfortunately, the nobility and the upper classes
undermined Turgot and his Six Edicts. He ran into
insurmountable opposition on the part of nobles, the clergy,
and the Parliament of Paris and was dismissed from his
position.
Turgot was a clearly
articulated defender of individual and economic freedom who
realized that interference with freedom can have systemic
effects. He observed that conditions in various markets are
interrelated through a reciprocal interdependence. He
understood the complex interrelations of the ingredients of
land, labor, capital, wages, production, consumption, and so
on in the economy. He had a grand conception of an open and
dynamic society. He said that government should be limited
to protecting individuals against injustices and the nation
against invasion. Turgot realized that free commerce was the
best protection against scarcity. He wanted to abolish
crushing taxes, trade restrictions, monopoly privileges, and
forced labor and to reduce government expenditures and
public debt. Turgot was opposed to military conscription and
protectionism. Although he desired freedom in foreign
commerce, he was most interested in eliminating restrictions
on France's internal trade. For example, he wanted to
introduce banking and taxation reforms. Turgot also wanted
to create a scientific system of weights and measures.
During his two years as
Minister of Finance, Turgot proposed a gradual progress of
deregulation that put trust in the operation of the open
market. His goal was to have general liberty in buying and
selling. Moderation and gradualism were his form of tactics.
His main efforts were to prepare the public for, and to
institute, reasonable and incremental reforms.
Turgot wanted to see
local self-government in France and ultimately a
constitutional government of the nation. He desired
political liberty and favored constitutional limits on royal
power as well as strong regional governments. Turgot
therefore proposed a hierarchy of elected assemblies going
from the village up to the national level. Although he was
sympathetic to American rebels, he himself would not
recommend that they go to war. He also warned Americans that
slavery is not in accord with a proper political
constitution. Turgot also cautioned America about the danger
of possible civil war.
Although Turgot was familiar with, and close to, the
Physiocrats with respect to their views on economics, he
goes further than they do and in a different direction. Like
the physiocrats, he promoted free trade and advocated a
single tax on the net product of land. He wanted taxes to be
shifted back to agriculture. Turgot agrees with the
physiocrats that, because ultimately only agriculture is
productive, there should be a single tax on land. Taxation
of land was thus the only proper source of revenue for the
state. He saw land as a unique form of wealth and presented
an early view of the law of diminishing returns in
agriculture. Turgot's ultimate goal was actually to
eliminate taxes. Not a full-fledged physiocrat, he was more
interested in abolishing taxes than exacting them on
agricultural land. However, as long as taxation was a
reality, his "ideal" in taxation would be a single
imposition levied only on land. Turgot recommended taxing
only the landowners and not the tenants.
In his writings on
progress, Turgot had analyzed the relationship between
agrarian and industrial organizations. He explained that the
development of commercial capital activates growth both in
the involved industries and in agriculture. According to
Turgot, industry yields a surplus that creates a demand, not
only for crafts and products created through new technology,
but also for products of the soil.
According to Turgot, each
person compares various economic goods, values them, forms
ordinal preference scales, and then chooses among them. He
does this while considering his present and future wants and
needs and the potential uses of the different economic
objects. Turgot saw that these values were subjective (i.e.,
personal) and not able to be measured in any way except
ordinally. Explaining the mutual benefits of free exchange,
Turgot states that exchange increases the wealth of both
parties. He also notes that each transactor wants to gain as
much as possible and to surrender as little as possible in a
given exchange. Like the much later F. A. Hayek, Turgot
spoke of the essential particular knowledge of subjective
individual actors who tend to act in their perceived
self-interest.
Turgot observed that the
subjective utility of an economic good decreases as its
supply to an individual increases – diminishing utility is a
function of abundance. A forerunner of the Marginalist
Revolution, Turgot conceived of the idea of diminishing
marginal productivity of factor inputs. Increasing the
quantity of some factors increases the marginal productivity
until a maximum point is attained. Past this point, the
marginal productivity will decrease, fall to zero, and
ultimately will turn negative. Each increase in input would
be less and less productive. Essentially, all that Turgot
lacked was the idea of the marginal unit.
Concerned with the
classical political economy of scarcity, Turgot saw
economics as the allocation of scarce resources to a number
of alternative ends. He understood that all costs are
opportunity costs because in choosing to employ resources in
one way a person has to give up using specific resources in
some other productive manner. Turgot views the
capitalist-entrepreneur as desiring to earn his imputed
salary plus the opportunity cost (today we would say lost
contribution margin) that he gave up by not investing his
money somewhere else.
Turgot observed that
natural resources must be converted to economic products
through the application of human labor and that production
takes time to take place. He thus recognized the critical
role of time in the production process. In addition, he
noted that capital in advance is essential to the production
process. The act of waiting, which is necessary in modern
production processes, must be rewarded by a return to the
suppliers of capital. This return is, at the minimum, equal
to the market rate of interest on the capital invested in
the company.
While products are being
worked on, there must be advance payments to laborers, who,
Turgot explains, are agreeable to paying the capitalists a
discount out of production in order to be paid money in
advance of the uncertain future revenues. He says that
capital advances are essential in all productive
enterprises. The interest return on investments can be
viewed as the price labor pays to capitalist-entrepreneurs
for advancing savings in the form of current money. Turgot
emphasized that the time element in production is a function
of the use of capital-intensive production methods, the
division of labor, and the demand for capital. He
apportioned the return to the capitalists into pure
interest, depreciation, and entrepreneurial payment that
includes a risk premium.
Turgot recognized that
capital was required for economic growth and that the only
way to amass capital was for individuals not to consume
everything that they had produced. He illuminated the
meaning of the term "surplus" and explained the link between
surplus and economic growth and progress. Turgot observed
that a prosperous economy depends upon the free flow of
capital – capital promotes economic activity. The greater
the amount of saving, the excess of income over consumption,
the higher the accumulation of capital will be. Savings are
accumulated in the form of money and then are invested in
capital goods. He explains that the advance of savings to
the factors of production is the essence of investment.
Turgot's savings and
capital formation analysis is one of his greatest
contributions in economics and it became the basis for the
19th century classical theory of savings and investment. He
demonstrated clearly the benefit of a policy of capital
accumulation and explained that money was essential to the
process of accumulating capital and generating economic
growth. Money was the required ingredient for transferring
savings into investment. Although the surplus accumulated
via savings could be held in commodities or in money, Turgot
explained that economic society languished before the
arrival of metallic money because of the extreme difficulty
of aggregating and transforming surplus production into
capital. Money allowed people to more easily accumulate and
employ their savings.
Money is also a commodity
and is not merely a conventional symbol. Turgot explains
that it is a form of wealth and has value in itself.
Metallic money is more than a sign of value. He said that
gold and silver are money by the nature of things and that
precious metals are one of the forms of capital. For him,
money was intrinsically valuable in the form of gold and
silver. He explained that money had to be a commodity having
intrinsic value for it to be useful as a medium of exchange.
Turgot was against the perspective that the government could
effectively issue paper money as a substitute for metallic
money. His favored order is one in which metallic money,
representing savings, is loaned to borrowers. Savings, in
the form of money, are loaned to entrepreneurs who desire to
invest. This money is channeled through moneylenders as
intermediaries. Some people earn interest income from loans
made to farmers, landowners, merchants, and industrialists.
Such financiers promoted the circulation of capital. Money
is vital for transferring savings into investments.
Interest, the price of
borrowed money, is determined by the supply and demand for
capital and is not immoral. To lend and borrow is the result
of a voluntary contract by two parties, each of whom hoped
to gain from the transaction. Turgot recognized that a loan
is a reciprocal contract between two parties because each
believed that it is advantageous to him. Because there exist
no exploitation in charging interest, Turgot says that usury
laws have been refuted.
Turgot understood that
the explanation for interest is time preference – the
phenomenon of discounting the future and of setting a
premium upon the present. He explains that the present
market value of a capital asset tends to equal the aggregate
of the expected annual future returns from it discounted by
the market rate of interest (or time preference). Turgot
also emphasized that an entrepreneur's expected profits must
exceed the loan rate of interest in order for a loan to have
taken place – he saw the relationship between the profit
rate and the interest rate.
Turgot asserted that the
rate of interest was determined in the market via exchange.
He perceived the relationship between the interest rate and
the quantity of money. More specifically, he observed the
interrelationship among the supply and demand for money and
people's time preferences which come together to affect the
relative amounts of spending and saving and the interest
rate. Turgot saw that a decrease in thrift would raise
interest rates and vice versa. He explained that a low
interest rate is a function of a high savings rate and that
a low interest rate propels the economy to high rates of
economic growth. Turgot noted that a change in the rate of
accumulated savings affects the interest rate which changes
the allocation of resources in the economy. He also talked
about the difference between the natural rate of interest
that would occur in a free economy and the actual interest
on loans (i.e., the difference between the real and nominal
rates of interest). Similarly, he distinguished between a
product's natural price and its market price.
Turgot said that money
can be employed to: (1) purchase land for cultivation or to
lease to farmers; (2) invest in industry by acquiring
buildings, materials, and tools for manufacturing; (3)
invest in agriculture by renting land and purchasing stock
and implements for agricultural entrepreneurship; (4) invest
in trade by buying finished goods and other requirements for
commercial activities; and (5) lend money to others for the
above purposes. According to Turgot, all these activities
either directly or indirectly return money to the circular
flow – there are no leakages. His analysis of savings and
investment thus foretells classical analysis which denies
the possibility of leakage from the exchange process and,
therefore, the possibility of a general glut of products. It
is clear that Turgot anticipated J.B. Say's Law of Markets.
Turgot was for the
freedom of domestic and foreign trade and against
mercantilist regulation, forced cartelization, and special
privileges conferred by the government. He said that
regulation involves expenses that become a tax on products –
the result is overcharging domestic customers and
discouraging foreign purchasers. He wanted sound money and
warned against the dangers of fiat paper money. Turgot also
explained that individual self-interest moves society
forward and is in accord with the general interest. He also
anticipated the diminishing marginal utility theory of Carl
Menger and others. Turgot explained that a person can only
pay taxes by reducing consumption and that there was no
logical basis for levying different rates on different
products. He, like the physiocrats, believed that the strain
of taxation should fall only on the owners of land because
of the very nature of the world. Turgot was a low-interest
advocate who contended that money was the foundation of
capital. He saw savings as a real phenomenon that facilitates
greater investment in the economy. For a busy man of affairs
who found little time to devote to economics, he certainly
has made some monumental contributions in that field.
|