These points are widely misunderstood even among
people who purport to be value investors. Grahamites do not, as is
often asserted, ignore market and economic conditions; nor do they
exclude these considerations from their analyses. Instead, they ask
questions such as: "how unusual are the results (profits, dividends,
etc.) that X Ltd has generated over the past 5-10 years? Have
monetary and overall economic conditions given these results an
artificial or unusually favourable boost? Given general corporate
"base rates" and those for similar companies, how likely is it that
these results can continue? Are there grounds to believe that X's
results in the future will regress towards some long-term mean? If
so, does a purchase at today's price provide a margin of safety that
sufficiently offsets the risk that X's future operations might not
match those of the present and recent past?"
Precisely because they draw conclusions about the prices of many
securities, Grahamites also hold views, which are rough and prone to
error, about market indices today and several years hence. And
because they form judgements about the normality or otherwise of
today's economic conditions, they also develop opinions about booms
and busts down the road.
Graham, for example, famously warned in the late 1950s about unduly
and perhaps dangerously high asset prices (see, for example, his
articles "The New Speculation in Common Stocks" and "Stock Market
Warning: Danger Ahead!"). Conversely, he rejoiced when in the mid-1970s
he detected attractively cheap prices (see "The Renaissance of
Value" and "The Future of Common Stocks," all of which appear in
Janet Lowe, ed., The Rediscovered Benjamin Graham: Selected Writings
of the Wall Street Legend, John Wiley & Sons, 1999). Similarly,
citing implausibly high prices and correspondingly meagre prospects,
in 1969 Warren Buffett closed his investment partnership. And at
several points since the late 1990s he has warned investors to
temper their expectations about the results they might reasonably
expect during the years and decades to come (for examples, see the
references on
Leithner & Co.'s links page).
Grahamites' views about markets, interest rates, overall
profitability, etc., thus play a distinctly second fiddle to their
analyses of individual companies and securities. They incorporate
these views into their individual analyses; but within these
analyses, company-specific factors and figures always predominate.
Their approach resembles that of Lawrence Sloan, who in Every Man
and His Common Stocks (McGraw-Hill, 1931) posed three questions
about the funk then gripping the U.S. (and most other countries).
First, was the country in the midst of a severe and possibly
prolonged slump? The answer, he believed, was "yes." Second, could
astute observers have discerned signs of trouble ahead of time?
Sloan thought that they could have; and one economist, Ludwig von
Mises, certainly did (see in particular Percy Greaves, ed., The
Causes of the Economic Crisis and Other Essays Before and After the
Great Depression, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2006).
Sloan's third
question is perhaps the most important. Could investors have
protected their portfolios from the Depression's worst effects?
Maybe but only if they were prepared to ignore the crowd and think
for themselves. The problem was that during the boom, signs of bust
were apparent only to those who sought them. As the Depression
unfolded, mixed and positive signs remained numerous enough to
persuade investors with optimistic and even neutral views of the
world that all would soon be well. Then and now, the most sensible
stance particularly when one's analysis of the past yields the
conclusion that today's prices and profits are improbably high, and
that tomorrow's harvest might be rather thin is to expect ructions,
adopt a rather dour attitude and incorporate cautious macro
possibilities into one's micro analyses. Mind the downside, in other
words, and the upside will mind itself.
How to apply this mindset to the conditions prevailing early in
2007? First, disregard high and possibly rising international
tensions. They are real, but much less severe than those prevailing
during most of the 20th century. Most notably,
the risk of terrorism
in Oz is trivial. Also, forget about the bird flu scare. As Jeffrey
Tucker shows in "Bush's Fowl Play," it is largely the concoction of
budget-maximising bureaucrats. Finally, ignore global warming. It's
a possibility; but so too, as Lawrence Solomon shows ("Will the Sun
Cool Us?"), is global cooling. And perhaps warming is a good thing.
Whatever it is, it's not a hard fact. It is, rather, an accelerating
barrow energetically pushed by (a) scientists whose status and
income depend upon the state and (b) politicians and other zealots
eagerly grasping the latest opportunity to aggrandise themselves and
plunder everybody else (see, for example, "Climate Chaos? Don't
Believe It" by Christopher Monckton). Even if global warming exists,
says
Bjorn Lomborg in
The Sceptical Environmentalist, the
interventions demanded to combat it will likely produce more harm
than good.
Put out of your mind, in short, the exotic and hypothetical risks
that are stirring ever more people into a collectivist frenzy.
Instead, focus upon a danger that is much more pedestrian, whose
evidence is much firmer, whose consequences politicians are doing
their best to ignore, and that has thus come to few investors'
attention. Why wait? Be the first on your block to recognise that
the U.S. Government likely is or before long will probably become
bankrupt.
Also, prepare financially and psychologically for the fallout that
might occur if and when people realise that Uncle Sam is broke. One
unambiguously good result would be the abandonment of the idiotic
(in its conception), inept (in its execution) and disastrous
(in its results) "war on terror." Even better would be the
consignment of America's interventionist foreign policy, which has
wrought so much damage upon so many people, including Americans, to
the same historical junkyard littered with the relics of Roman,
British, French, Russian and other imperialisms. Only people with a
material or reputational interest in warfare, such as the laptop
bombardiers on the editorial page of The Australian and The
Decider's lapdogs in Canberra, have anything to fear from the
resurrection of George Washington's
Farewell Address and America's
return to its Jeffersonian roots. The power the anointed lose is the
liberty the benighted recover.
Another positive (younger people are more likely to enjoy its
benefits) of America's bankruptcy would be the drastic pruning of
and the weaning of people from Social Security, Medicare and other
alleged government "benefits." The bad news for all Americans is
that their taxes may well rise steeply; and for everybody, Americans
and non-Americans, Uncle Sam's lurch towards insolvency implies
significantly higher inflation and interest rates. That, in turn,
augurs poorly for most financial assets.
Let's Define and Quantify
Our Terms |
Laurence Kotlikoff, in a must-read paper entitled "Is the United
States Bankrupt?" and published in 2006 by the St Louis branch of the
U.S. Federal Reserve, concludes that "countries can go broke, that
the United States is going broke, that remaining open to foreign
investment can help stave off bankruptcy, but that radical reform of
U.S. fiscal institutions is essential to secure the nation's
economic future
Unless the United States moves quickly to
fundamentally change and restrain its fiscal behaviour, its
bankruptcy will become a foregone conclusion." Fed Chairman Benjamin
Bernanke, in his testimony to the Committee on the Budget of the
U.S. Senate (Long-term
Fiscal Challenges Facing the United States,
18 January 2007), used much more diplomatic and less apoplectic
language, but did not reject or even question Kotlikoff's
conclusion.
Is the American Leviathan destitute? Clearly not: it continues to
possess an impressive ability to confiscate from Peter, lavish much
booty among its legions of vassals and mascots, and distribute the
rest among the Pauls whom it wishes to control. How, then, can one
possibly contend that Uncle Sam is or is going bankrupt? Beginning
in the 1930s, with another spurt in the 1960s and climaxing during
George W. Bush's presidency, he has made promises to his growing
hordes of dependents and foreign creditors that, as time passes, he
will be less and less able to fulfil. The U.S. Government is
insolvent in the sense that the net present value (NPV) of its
liabilities greatly exceeds the NPV of its assets (or the assets it
can be expected to raise in order to meet these liabilities).
Leviathan is bust in the sense that, given its vast present and
growing future shortfall of assets relative to liabilities ("fiscal
gap"), at some stage it must acknowledge reality, liquidate and
retrench. It is broke in the sense that, as occurs in many workouts,
it will pay its dependents and creditors less than it originally
promised them (see also "Broken
Army, Broken Empire" by Pat Buchanan).
Although it doesn't explicitly say so, the U.S. Government or, rather, a recent (15 December 2006) Treasury/OMB report entitled
Financial Report of the United States Government concurs (see also
"GAO Chief Warns Economic Disaster Looms" and
"Demographic
Reality and the Entitlement State" by Ron Paul). During 2006, the fiscal gap
continued to swell rapidly and now stands at ca. $53 trillion. And
that's just at the federal level. One could increase it by adding
various local and state shortfalls. Further, this figure assumes the
continuation of short- and medium-term economic sunshine, i.e., that nominal GDP will grow at a rate of
at least
5% per annum during the next five years. In other words, because the
Treasury's projections do not incorporate economic weakness, this
estimate of $53 trillion could easily err on the low side.
As a related matter, it's important to emphasise that there's literally!
no accounting for the U.S. Government. Its internal
auditor, Government Accountability Office, found for the tenth year
in succession that Uncle Sam's financial statements are unreliable
and that his financial controls are inadequate (see the Comptroller
General's
comment
on this year's Financial Report). The U.S.
Government is bankrupt in the sense that, by private sector
standards, its financial condition is not just unaudited: it is
simply unauditable.
The Pentagon's balance sheet, for example, is laughably crude. It
does not emerge from standard methods: instead, an estimated list of
liabilities is simply subtracted from a vague list of assets. A
report compiled in 2003 by its own Inspector General stated "we
identified $1.1 trillion [yes, that's a "t" and not a "b"] in
department-level accounting entries to financial data used to
prepare DoD component financial statements that were not supported
by adequate audit trails or by sufficient evidence to determine
their validity. In addition, we also identified $107 billion in
department-level accounting entries to financial data used to
prepare DoD component financial statements that were improper
because the entries were illogical or did not follow accounting
principles. . . . [In conclusion], DoD did not fully comply with the
laws and regulations that had a direct and material effect on its
ability to determine financial statement amounts."
More generally, the financial management of most (up to 20) of the
federal government's 24 largest agencies fails to meet requirements
enacted by Congress in 1996. Uncle Sam resembles nothing so much as
an inept, hopelessly spendthrift and disorganised man who hurriedly
stuffs a shoebox full of whatever documents and receipts he can find
and then throws the mess into a bewildered accountant's lap. In
the private sector, people who generate waste and loss face the ire
of shareholders, are usually denied access to capital, often receive
pink slips and running shoes and sometimes find themselves in gaol.
In the coercive sector, however, mismanagement is virtually never
punished: indeed, it is typically lauded and rewarded.
Also note that this fiscal gap does not incorporate the costs
associated with the invasions and occupations of Iraq and
Afghanistan. In "The Economic Costs of the Iraq
War," Joseph Stiglitz
and Linda Bilmes estimate that its NPV is $1 trillion or more, and
growing
(see also "Inflation:
The Hidden Cost of War" by Ron Paul). This, to
put it mildly, is somewhat higher than the initial and breezily
confident estimates of Administration and neocon insiders. Defence
Secretary Ronald Dumsfeld, for example, opined (19 January
2003) "well, the Office of Management and Budget has come up with a
number that's something under $50 billion
How much of that would
be the U.S.'s burden, and how much would be other countries', is an
open question."
A study by Jagadeesh Gokhale and Kent Smetters ("Measuring
Social Securitys Financial Problems," NBER Working Paper No.
11060, January 2005) concluded that the U.S. Government's "fiscal
gap" is closer to $65.9 trillion. That's more than 500% of America's
annual GDP and 200% of its accumulated wealth. The $53 trillion
estimate equates to ca. 400% of America's GDP in
2006, and has increased from about $20 trillion an amount
equivalent to 200% of GDP in 2000. (As a comparison, the net debt of
Her Majesty's Government is £490 billion. That's equivalent to
$US950 billion and to 38% of Britain's GDP. Adding the NPV of "off
balance sheet" liabilities produces an amount that approximates 100%
of its GDP.)
Finally, note that Treasury has expressed this $53 trillion fiscal
gap as a net present value. To make it disappear in the future
Uncle Sam must confiscate that amount now from his subjects and deposit
it in bank accounts earning hefty rates of interest (the GAO uses
5.7% as the assumed long-term rate of return). But in Main Street
U.S.A., these deposit rates do not exist. Because they didn't
collect interest on the money that they didn't deposit into these
hypothetical accounts this year, Americans will have to "deposit"
even more next year. As a matter of elementary maths, 5.7% of $53
trillion is a bit more than $3 trillion an amount ca. 15 times
greater than Uncle Sam's present annual budget deficit. Even if the
deficit suddenly became a very large surplus of, say, $500 billion
and remained at this level (a very unlikely proposition), the fiscal
gap would still continue to rise relentlessly. Accordingly, during
the next year it will likely swell by at least another $3 trillion
plus whatever additional outrages the Racketeers in the White House
and on Capitol Hill can devise. So for the sake of argument let's
add another $4 trillion, making a total of $57 trillion, as an early
guess of the fiscal gap in 2008. In last year's Financial Report,
the Treasury downplayed the gap. But this year their talk is tougher.
They state "the net social insurance responsibilities (scheduled
benefits in excess of estimated revenues) indicate that those
programs are on an unsustainable fiscal path and difficult choices
will be necessary in order to address their large and growing long-term
fiscal imbalance." Further, "delay is costly and choices will be
more difficult as the retirement of the 'baby boom' gets closer to
becoming a reality with the first wave of boomers eligible for
retirement under Social Security in 2008."
What do the present magnitude, the growth in the recent past and the
plausible rate of growth in the near future of the U.S. Government's
fiscal gap mean? As Chris Martenson notes in the
"United
States Is Insolvent," they imply three things.
First, it's
unlikely that America can "grow out of the problem." Uncle Sam's
financial position has deteriorated by over $22 trillion in 4
years and by $4.5 trillion during the last 12 months (see the
table below, extracted from this year's Report). The economic
sunshine of the past three years has not reduced the gap. Quite the contrary: it has widened and is deteriorating
ever more rapidly.
If the fiscal gap can balloon so quickly during allegedly good
times, what might happen if and when the economic horizon
darkens? It is unlikely, to put it mildly, that any economic
weakness will alleviate it.
Second, for many Americans, particularly younger ones and
those completely dependent upon Leviathan, the future portends
stagnant and perhaps much lower standards of living. How to
close the fiscal gap? According to Laurence Kotlikoff, "the
answers are terrifying. One solution is an immediate and
permanent doubling of personal and corporate income taxes.
Another is an immediate and permanent two-thirds cut in Social
Security and Medicare benefits. A third alternative, were it
feasible [as if the first two were politically palatable!] would
be to immediately and permanently cut all federal discretionary
spending by 143% [i.e., to eliminate all such spending and run
a mammoth and unprecedented budget surplus]." When pigs fly
Third, history shows us that every government that has so
incompetently managed its finances has tried to "print its way
out of trouble." Do American politicians possess generous
amounts of the courage required to fix this mess? Given their
country's fiscal problems, the prancing and babble of its
presidential hopefuls, and the posturing and preening of
politicians more generally, is at best a self-deception and at
worst a cruel hoax upon the public. If they truly sought, in Ms
Pelosi's words, "to build a better future for all of America's
children," then they would drastically prune if not completely
abolish the welfare-warfare state. |
The truth, of course, is that the Fed cannot
painlessly inflate, nor the pollies prattle, America's way out of
this predicament. But no matter: because draconian cuts of
expenditure are not realistic solutions to its impending bankruptcy,
inflation is a much more likely possibility. Inflation today that
is, the central bank's expansion of the money supply reduces the
purchasing power of money tomorrow. Thanks to the central bank's
inflation, the extent of debts (measured in nominal dollar amounts)
may remain unchanged or even rise; but as purchasing power falls, so
too do real values. Inflation thus imposes a hidden tax upon its
victims. What's the material difference between (a) 0% inflation and
the confiscation of x% of your money and (b) x% inflation and no
overt confiscation? Nothing: in each case, your purchasing power
falls by x%.
The rhetorical difference, of course, is that (a) is political
suicide and (b) is ignored or misrepresented in the mainstream
media. (Its demand that the central bank deliver "low interest
rates" is, in effect, a demand that the bank generate high
inflation; and the phrases "steady inflation" and "the gradual
destruction of the purchasing power of money" are virtual synonyms.)
Do not, therefore, expect that you will rise one morning to
headlines proclaiming that Uncle Sam is broke. Instead, anticipate
that it will be an extended and covert affair. The central bank's
inflation can promote only two things: the size and waste of the
welfare-warfare state and the penury of the middle and battler
classes. Indeed, to the extent that the U.S. Government's bankruptcy
takes the form of an enrichment of privileged "insiders" and the
gradual impoverishment of benighted "outsiders," it commenced years
ago and is proceeding silently apace.
The reality, then, is that Americans and non-Americans are likely to
face a future of uncomfortably high inflation and possibly worse
if somewhere down the track the $US loses its privileged status as
the world's reserve currency.
In the Beginning, There Was Debt |
Laurence Kotlikoff notes correctly that solvency need have nothing
to do with indebtedness. A particular government, for example, might
year after year maintain its budget in surplus and never borrow a
penny. It might laud itself as a model of fiscal prudence. But if
its liabilities outstrip its assets, and if it cannot raise the
assets required to meet its liabilities at 100 cents on the dollar
when they fall due, then this alleged model of rectitude is actually
insolvent. "To summarise," says Kotlikoff, "countries can go
bankrupt but whether or not they are bankrupt or are going bankrupt
can't be discerned from their 'debt' policies. 'Debt' in economics,
like distance and time in physics, is in the eyes (or mouth) of the
beholder."
Well said. Yet Kotlikoff overreaches when he says "the focus on
government debt has no more scientific basis than reading tea leaves
or examining entrails." Quite the contrary: although one must infer
cautiously, the source, timing and growth profile of the U.S.
Government's "on-balance sheet" debt can teach us much about
America's rise and fall, the causes of its present pickle and the
possible source of its redemption (see also William Bonner and
Addison Wiggins, Empire of Debt: The Rise of an Epic Financial
Crisis, John Wiley & Sons, 2006). America's founder knew the lesson,
but their descendents have ignored it. In James Madison's words, war
is the most serious threat to liberty and solvency "because it
comprises and develops the germ of every other. War is the parent of
armies; from these proceed debts and taxes; and armies and debts and
taxes are the known instruments for bringing the many under the
domination of the few."
Wars and economic "emergencies" are catnip
to politicians because it is during these times that the
government's powers and patronage can be extended most rapidly and thus the individual harnessed most securely to the yoke of the
state. According to H.L. Mencken (Notes on Democracy, Knopf, 1926),
"the whole history of the [U.S.] has been a history of melodramatic
pursuits of horrendous monsters, most of them imaginary: the red-coats,
the Hessians, the monocrats, again the red-coats, the Bank, the
Catholic, the slave power, Jeff Davis, Mormonism, Wall Street, the
rum demon, John Bull, the hell hounds of plutocracy, the trusts, ...
Pancho Villa, German spies, the Kaiser, Bolshevism. The list might
be lengthened indefinitely: a complete chronicle of the Republic
could be written in terms of it, without omitting a single important
episode." In this respect, the "war on terror" is simply the most
recent display in a long catalogue of deceptions. Monroe concludes
that during wars and emergencies, an "inequality of fortunes, and
the opportunities of fraud, growing out of a state of war, and ... degeneracy of manners and of morals [develops] ... No nation could
preserve its freedom in the midst of continual warfare." Certainly
the U.S. hasn't (see in particular Robert Higgs, Crisis and
Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government,
Oxford UP, 1987).
The trouble is that, since time immemorial, rulers have sought to
wage war. And to do so, they must confiscate their subjects'
property. Since the 1720s, when Sir Robert Walpole revolutionised
the financial basis of the British Government, a government able to
command the confidence of lenders has also been able to issue debt
that need never be repaid. It needs only to create a regular and
dependable source of revenue a "tax base" and then use a part of
it to pay the annual interest and the principal of maturing bonds.
For every bond it retires, it also issues a new one. In this way, a
"national debt" becomes a perpetual debt. It thereby becomes an
instrument of unending war. The Royal Navy extended British
sovereignty and influence around much of the world during the 18th
and 19th centuries, and Walpole's innovation underwrote its
activities. The establishment of a national debt not only overturned
the fear of Stuart tyranny: ironically, it entrenched Jacobite
objectives into the heart of British government. HMG, in other words,
could now maintain a permanent military establishment and finance
its wars without the regular and bothersome application to
Parliament. The British Empire, then, was built upon more than the
blood of soldiers, sailors and civilians: it was a superstructure,
and a permanent national debt was its foundation. This debt had the
added benefit (to politicians) of harnessing creditors to the
government.
These developments did not escape the attention of the America's
founders. In January 1789, when General Washington mounted the steps
of Federal Hall (close to the top of Wall Street and opposite
today's New York Stock Exchange), took the oath of office and became
the first President, his newborn country's Treasury was virtually
empty. It was also burdened by debts of $77 million an amount
equivalent to ca. 30% of the new country's rudimentary GDP (this and
subsequent historical debt-to-GDP ratios have been derived from
Donald Stabile and Jeffrey Cantor, The Public Debt of the United
States: An Historical Perspective, 1775-1990, Praeger, 1991). The
rebellion against Britain had cost treasure as well as blood, and
the colonists were only slightly more willing to submit to local
than to Imperial taxes. Under the Articles of Confederation, the
admirably loose-fitting constitutional garment that had joined the
rebellious colonies, the nascent federal government possessed no
power to tax. The states could levy taxes and forward them to the
Continental Congress; but they too were hobbled by debt, and popular
hostility towards taxes was pervasive. Hence little more than a
trickle of funds flowed into the Congress's coffers (see also
Stabile's The Origins of American Public Finance: Debates over
Money, Debt, and Taxes in the Constitutional Era, 1776-1836,
Greenwood, 1998).
Alternative means were therefore sought to finance the war. As it is
doing today, Congress resorted to external creditors and the
domestic printing press (see in particular Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States: the Colonial Era
to World War II, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2002). As a result, by
the time Washington vanquished Cornwallis in 1783, American
governments owed large sums to King Louis of France, to Dutch
bankers and the thousands of American soldiers, farmers and
merchants who had lent their labour, goods and capital to the cause.
Virtually all agreed that it had been right and proper to borrow in
order to secure their political independence.
But what about the new country's financial sovereignty? Over the
next two decades, how indeed, whether the debt would be repaid
and the budget balanced became the subject of a ferocious debate
between two leading lights: Thomas Jefferson and Alexander Hamilton.
"Hamilton was indeed a singular character," Jefferson wrote of his
rival. "Of acute understanding, disinterested, honest, and
honourable in all private transactions, amiable in society, and duly
valuing virtue in private life, yet so bewitched and perverted by
the British example, as to be under thorough conviction that
corruption was essential to the government of a nation." It is only
a slight exaggeration to say that their fiscal contest was the seed
that germinated "factions" and party politics in the U.S. Washington
sat uncomfortably between them at the cabinet table and lamented the
"internal dissensions" that were "tearing our vitals."
To most early Americans, the very existence of public debt and
deficit was inexcusable. Many likened it to the seizure of property
without the owner's consent. Amassing debt to finance grandiose
national projects, and then extending this debt into perpetuity, was
widely regarded as monarchical, English and corrupting. But to a few
ιlites, most notably Hamilton and his mentor, Robert Morris, debt
was just another word for money; money was a potent form of power;
and power, they believed, was their birthright. "The [national] debt
was a tremendous source of power," wrote William Anderson in The
Price of Liberty: The Public Debt of the American Revolution (University
of Virginia Press, 1983), "for whoever controlled it would in all
likelihood possess not only the chief taxing power but the prime
allegiance of a large segment of the American population" (see also
"Perpetual
Debt: From the British Empire to the American Hegemon" by
Scott Trask, which inspired the structure of the next couple of
pages).
Jefferson, whom Washingon appointed as America's first Secretary of
State, agreed and hastened to add that the very existence of a
national debt, to say nothing of its growth, would centralise
political and economic influence into a small number of privileged
hands. It would thereby foment some of the very injustices that had
prompted people to migrate to America and had prompted Americans
to rebel against George III. Legally and ethically, said Jefferson,
"we should consider ourselves unauthorised to saddle posterity with
our debts, and morally bound to pay them ourselves."
|