Long wars, it stands to reason, require deep pockets.
But more guns, “leaders” have assured their subjects, do not imply
less butter. Quite the contrary: spending of all kinds will rise
sharply. Not only are present “commitments” sacrosanct: other
bribes, particularly medical subsidies required to assuage aging
populations, will rise drastically. The anointed of America’s tax-consuming
caste state quite unapologetically, and its benighted tax-producers
accept credulously, how the state will finance these obligations:
the U.S. Government will graciously borrow and foreigners will
dutifully lend. The true “coalition of the willing” comprises the
savers and lenders of Asia and Europe. They underwrite America’s
welfare at home and its warfare around the world.
Today, surprisingly few people question whether this “long war” is
financially feasible; and virtually nobody is willing to canvass the
likelihood that it and the government’s other grandiose ambitions
will, in effect, push Uncle Sam into receivership (see, however,
"Avoid the Rush: Prepare Now for America’s Bankruptcy"). For better or
worse, perceptions about the U.S. Government’s creditworthiness
calibrate the world’s economic and financial thermostat. For decades
the conviction has been wide, deep and seemingly impregnable: U.S.
Treasury securities are the planet’s safest credit risk. The yield
of a Treasury bill has been the benchmark (or “risk-free”) rate of
return; and other assets (ranging from American corporate bonds to
European stocks to New Zealand real estate) are priced, if only
indirectly, relative to its yield. In recent years, the yields of
Treasury bills and bonds have stood at or near generational lows.
These ultra-low yields have helped to generate what by historical
standards are very high – and perhaps dangerously high – asset
prices.
But what if these yields are far lower than they ought to be? What
if, ironically, the “risk-free” rate is actually fraught with risk,
and Uncle Sam’s sovereign credit rating overstates his
creditworthiness? If so, then a disturbing possibility presents
itself: in the future this rating may be downgraded – conceivably to
“junk” levels. If that happens, then, to put it mildly, financial
and economic shocks will reverberate around the world.
Whether it occurs gradually or suddenly, any change to the overall
perception about America’s creditworthiness will, mostly through
upward pressure upon interest rates and downward pressure upon
securities’ prices, greatly influence financial markets and
standards of living. The stark reality is that if the financial
statements and debt securities of the U.S. Government were analysed
objectively – that is, by the same standards used to judge
developing countries like, say, Botswana – then its pristine credit
rating would fall. (Memo to Britons, Frenchmen, Germans and Japanese:
your governments are also paddling in leaky boats.) This conclusion
is not iconoclastic: one major ratings agency, Standard & Poor’s,
has taken it seriously enough to explore its implications (see in
particular
In The Long Run, We Are All Debt: Aging Societies and
Sovereign Ratings).
America’s national debt has increased from $77m in 1789 to $8.8
trillion (and rising rapidly) today. Its unfunded (“off-balance
sheet”) liabilities are at least $53 trillion, perhaps as high as
$70 trillion, and are climbing rapidly. But most people either
ignore or discount these developments. Yes, since the late 18th
century debt has risen to hitherto unimaginable heights – but so too
have standards of living. Observing this correlation, today’s
conventional wisdom infers that spending, particularly the debt-financed
variety, causes prosperity. More of the former, they believe,
necessarily produces more of the latter. This is America, its
residents and their rulers proudly assert; and they act as if the
laws of economics simply don’t apply to them. Debts and deficits, to
use the notorious phrase attributed to Dick Cheney,
simply don’t
matter. Major credit rating agencies apparently agree: despite the
mountains of debt and their brisk rate of expansion, all award the
U.S. the highest possible sovereign rating. The higher the rating,
the lower is the perception that a government will repudiate its
obligations, and the lower is the rate of interest creditors agree
to receive from the amounts they lend. On that basis, everybody
believes that Uncle Sam’s promises are as good as gold.
This perception raises the question: exactly how is a country’s
sovereign credit rating derived? Agencies do not reveal all of their
methods. But in "Determinants and Impact of Sovereign Credit Ratings"
(Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic Policy Review, October
1996), Richard Cantor and Frank Packer analysed handful of key
variables. They also remind us why a country’s rating is important:
among other things, it exerts a strong influence upon the ratings
assigned to corporate borrowers domiciled within that country.
Agencies seldom if ever assign a rating to a municipality,
provincial government or private company that is higher than that of
the issuer’s national government. This rule of thumb could one day
put agencies into an interesting bind. What, for example, would
happen to the spotless ratings of top-flight companies such as
Berkshire Hathaway if the U.S. Government’s rating were downgraded?
Sovereign ratings and changes thereto have vital implications for
investors, individual and corporate, around the world; and to
analyse and apply Cantor and Packer’s key rating variables
dispassionately is an eye-opening exercise (see also Eric Englund’s
"Should the US Government’s Sovereign Credit Rating be Downgraded to
Junk?").
The higher the average income within a country, note Cantor and
Packer, the bigger its government’s potential tax base. The bigger
the flock and the fatter its geese, the more the government can
steal. The more rapidly average income rises, in turn, the more
secure (from the state’s, as opposed to the income earner’s, point
of view!) the tax base; and the bigger and more secure a potential
tax-base relative to the state’s borrowings, the stronger is its
ability to repay debt.
Uncle Sam’s debts and liabilities, as well as American households’
debts and liabilities, are growing more rapidly than Americans’
“real” (i.e., net of CPI) incomes. The rate of growth of real
disposable personal income grew by 2.9% per year during the decade
to
2003. Since 2001 or so, this rate has been little related to the
growth of real GDP (see, for example,
these charts and comments). In
2005 it plunged to ca. 0%. It rebounded in 2006, to a rate of more
than 4% per year, but more recently has been decelerating. As a
result, since 1990 and net of CPI, Americans’ incomes have grown by
ca. 2-3% per year.
In 2005, the average household earned $45,000 of after-tax income
and owed approximately $8,000 of credit card debt, $12,000 of other
consumer debt and $65,000 of mortgage debt. It devoted approximately
13% of its after-tax income to the repayment of interest and
principal. This figure, known as the “debt-service ratio,” has in
recent years remained slightly above 13%, whereas the financial
obligations ratio (which incorporates other recurring expenses such
as rents, auto leases, homeowners’ insurance and property taxes that
decrease the uncommitted income otherwise available to households)
has hovered a bit above 18%. (For details, see
Credit Card Industry
Facts and Personal Debt Statistics and
American Housing Survey for
the United States: 2005.)
Since 1990, the average household’s total debt has increased at ca.
6.6% per year and roughly 40-50% of households, particularly lower-income
ones, presently spend more than they earn. Also since 1990, the sum
of Uncle Sam’s on- and off-balance sheet obligations has increased
at roughly 7.5% per year (see, for example,
U.S. National Debt Clock
FAQ). As the habit of saving has collapsed (the personal savings
rate as measured by the St Louis branch of the Federal Reserve has
fallen from 8.5% in the 1970s to 7.5% in the 1980s to 5.0% in the
1990s to less than 0.0% since 2002), the indulgence of borrowing has
exploded. During the past decade, consumers’ incomes have probably –
but not by a wide margin – outpaced their current expenditures. But
in two respects consumers have been fortunate. First, until recently
price rises in the supermarket, at the petrol bowser, etc. have been
restrained. Second, very low rates of interest have mitigated the
impact of the growing burden of debt. But what if the CPI and
interest rates revert towards longer term (multi-decade) averages?
If prices and rates rise at a quicker pace, then pressures upon
households will magnify. Under these conditions, households would
experience the “magic of compounding” in reverse.
“In evaluating household debt burdens,” said Alan Greenspan ("Understanding
Household Debt Obligations," 23 February 2004), “one must remember
that debt-to-income ratios have been rising for at least a half
century. With household assets rising as well, the ratio of net
worth to income is currently somewhat higher than its long-run
average. So long as financial intermediation continues to expand [that’s
bureaucratese for “as long as anybody who needs to borrow can do so
on easy terms”], both household debt and assets are likely to rise
faster than income.” In James Grant’s apt phrase, America’s
“leveraged condition” is proceeding apace. Alas, trees do not grow
to the heavens, actions have consequences and debt must be serviced
and ultimately repaid. Can households’ balance sheets forever expand
more quickly than their income statements?
But Dr Greenspan seemed to be relaxed. “Without an examination of
what is happening to both assets and liabilities, it is difficult to
ascertain the true burden of debt service. Overall, the household
sector seems to be in good shape, and much of the apparent increase
in the household sector’s debt ratios over the past decade reflects
factors that do not suggest increasing household financial stress.
And, in fact, during the past two years, debt service ratios have
been stable.” All true – at a time when mortgage rates were very low,
the prices of residential real estate buoyant and virtually anybody
who wanted a loan could get one. Do we still live in such times?
Will we do so during the next 5-10 years?
Hence another interpretation – one that might more accurately
describe a time when the market price of residential housing, which
comprises the bedrock of the typical household’s net worth, is (at
best) rising more slowly than hitherto, is stagnant in many areas
and is (at worst) falling. Modest rates of growth of personal income,
brisk rates of growth of personal and governmental debt and high
absolute levels of debt – in these respects, America’s tax base may
rest upon less-than-impregnably-solid foundations. If a country’s
sovereign credit rating depends upon its government’s ability to
confiscate, then the robber’s ability to plunder ultimately depends
upon its victims’ financial health. Just as many Americans (like
many Australians, Britons, Canadians, New Zealanders, etc.) who buy
petrol and shop in supermarkets suspect that the CPI is rising more
quickly than their rulers admit, they are also right to wonder
whether they are actually in less robust financial shape than their
overlords claim.
The External Balance of Trade and Finance
|
A deficit with the rest of the world indicates that a country’s
public and private sectors (considered as a whole) import some
combination of goods, services and capital from abroad. To consume
and invest more than one earns and saves is to borrow from the rest
of the world; and persistent and growing deficits increase
indebtedness to foreigners. The greater the debt and the quicker the
rate of growth of obligations, say Cantor and Packer, the less
creditworthy is the country.
Are Americans living beyond their means? No doubt some of them have
been, and the sub-prime mortgage imbroglio may well reveal that
their number is considerably greater than previously reckoned. But
even if the mortgage and residential real estate woes are deeper and
last longer than the optimists expect, it’s extremely unlikely that
Americans as a whole are candidates for bankruptcy. Is the U.S.
Government living way beyond its means? Almost certainly. A review
of American imports and exports of goods, services and capital that
distinguishes clearly between individuals/private businesses on the
one hand and governments on the other helps to corroborate these
points.
A first important point is that since the Second World War (and
probably since the early 19th century), individuals’ and businesses’ purchases of goods from abroad have tended to be producer goods (such
as machinery, semi-finished goods, etc.) rather than consumer goods
(such as plasma screen TVs, etc.). Further, during the past several
decades the composition of private sector imports has changed
notably. Consumption goods have comprised a steadily falling – and
production goods a steadily growing – percentage of all imports. The
classification of imports makes it difficult to distinguish producer
from consumer goods. Nonetheless, and according to Sudha Shenoy ("Is
America Living Beyond Its Means? Is That the Right Question?"),
consumer goods constituted a bit less than one-third of private
sector imports in the 1950s and 1960s, a quarter in the 1970s and
ca. 23% in
2004. Further, American business’ holdings of cash are presently
near an historical high and their borrowings relatively low. Hence
it does not appear that American individuals and businesses are
borrowing against (or selling) assets in order to finance the
purchase of foreign consumer goods.
A second point is that before ca. 1980 the U.S. was a net exporter
of goods and capital; since then, it has become a net importer of
all three. Since the early 19th century, America’s private sector
has imported capital from Europe. It still does, and Europe remains
the single biggest source of foreign capital. According to Shenoy,
Europe supplied 68% of total direct foreign investment in 1960 and
71% in 2004. Canada provided 28% of the total in 1960 but just 9% in
2004. Japan and all others provided 4% in 1960 and 20% in 2004.
Indirect (a.k.a. “portfolio”) investment – that is, buying shares
of companies rather than directly buying land and entire businesses
– has risen from a rather low base in the 1960s and now comprises a
majority of foreign investment in the U.S. According to some, this
reflects the attractions of American investments compared to
non-American ones. Perhaps.
Related to this second point is the rough correlation between the
U.S. household savings ratio and rising tide of capital imports.
Over the decades, American households have “outsourced” their
savings to foreigners. The savings which American households once
supplied to American banks (who then lent it to American businesses)
is now supplied mostly by foreigners. The gratification which
Americans once deferred – that is, the discipline to save and
consume less today in order to spend and consume more tomorrow – is
now held much less in check than it used to be. And although current
income continues to finance most of American households’ consumption,
a growing portion derives from borrowings (including borrowing
against “home equity”) and the sale of assets. Some Americans, then,
have been borrowing against (or selling) assets in order to finance
the purchase of (mostly domestically produced) consumer goods.
The bull in the China shop is clearly the U.S. Government. As the
supply of domestic savings has shrunk, Leviathan’s demands have
grown – and have thereby generated additional (i.e., in addition to private sector demand) and very large inflows of capital. These
borrowings began to rise in the 1980s (to ca. 17% of all capital
inflows), and since then have risen 2.5 times more quickly than
foreign inflows into the private sector. By 2004, 34% of capital
imported into the U.S. was earmarked for Uncle Sam’s domestic
welfare and international warfare. In Shenoy’s words, “beyond
argument, this is the exemplar of borrowing capital to finance
current spending.” Although he wasn’t so blunt, Fed Chairman
Benjamin Bernanke’s testimony to the Committee on the Budget of the
U.S. Senate ("Long-term Fiscal Challenges Facing the United States,"
18 January) did not disagree.
What the Mainstream Calls “Inflation” |
A high rate of “inflation” – that is, of growth of CPI – is,
according to Cantor and Packer, a sign that structural problems are
afflicting the government and its finances. The more marked the
tendency of consumer prices to rise, the less secure the
government’s tax base, the less creditworthy the government and
hence the riskier the debt it issues.
Like Alan Greenspan before him, Ben Bernanke never tires of
emphasising that the CPI – whose rise, he always omits to mention,
is an eventual consequence of inflation – is, compared to the 1970s
and 1980s, quiescent. To the extent that the Man in the Street
thinks about him, Dr Bernanke generates cognitive dissonance.
Americans know full well (because they buy groceries and petrol)
that some prices that are not supposed to rise are nevertheless
steadily rising; and because they read the real estate section of
the newspaper and look at estate agents’ displays, they see that
some prices that are supposed to rise are not (or aren’t rising
quickly enough). Yet they believe – and politicians fervently trust
– that The Chairman has everything under control.
According to John Williams ("Government Economic Reports: Things
You’ve Suspected But Were Afraid to Ask!" Part IV), however, the
hunches of the Man in the Street are correct:
Inflation, as reported by the Consumer Price Index (CPI), is
understated by roughly 7% per year. This is due to recent
redefinitions of the series as well as to flawed methodologies … In
particular, changes made in CPI methodology during the Clinton
Administration understated inflation significantly … In a like
manner, anyone involved in commerce, who relies on receiving
payments adjusted for the CPI, has been similarly damaged. On the
other side, if you are making payments based on the CPI (i.e., the federal government), you are making out like a bandit.
Williams concludes:
Traditional inflation rates can be estimated by adding 7.0% to the
CPI-U annual growth rate (3.8% +7.0% = 10.8% as of August 2006) or
by adding 7.4% to the C-CPI-U rate (3.4% + 7.4% = 10.8% as of August
2006) (see also "Haute Con Job" by Bill Gross).
|
Doug Noland of The Prudent Bear shares neither central bankers’
opinion about the CPI nor the general public’s (or financial
journalists’) opinion about central bankers. On 31 December 2004 he
wrote in his Credit Bubble Bulletin:
The U.S. economy is in the midst of a distorted boom, with an
increasingly ingrained inflationary bias. Asset bubbles are heavily
influencing spending and investing patterns, hence the underlying
structure of the economy. The nature of the U.S. bubble economy –
where gross financial excess is required to fuel minimally
acceptable employment gains – will be an issue for 2005. Current
market rates and liquidity conditions appear poised to initially
foster stronger-than-expected demand domestically and globally,
although the unstable and unbalanced nature of the current global
expansion will continue to provide fodder for those arguing for an
imminent slowdown. I expect the Chinese and Asian inflationary booms
to become increasingly problematic. Energy and commodities will
remain in tight supply, with prices extraordinarily volatile but
with a continued upward bias. The current minority Fed view that [a
rising CPI] and marketplace speculation pose increasing risks has
potential to become consensus. And I can certainly envisage a
scenario of increasingly anxious central bankers eyeing inflationary
pressures and unstable markets across the globe. |
|
Growth of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) |
If a country enjoys a relatively high rate of economic growth,
Cantor and Packer reckon, then the burden of debt that exists at any
point in time will, if it remains stable or grows more slowly than
GDP, become easier to service over time. It is surely a coincidence!
Tell us it isn’t so! Not only does the CPI understate the extent to
which American prices are rising: GDP figures exaggerate the extent
to which the American economic pie is growing. Williams states in
Part V of his series
The Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is one of the broader measures of
economic activity and is the most widely followed business indicator
reported by the U.S. Government. Upward growth biases built into GDP
modelling since the early 1980s, however, have rendered this
important series nearly worthless as an indicator of economic
activity … The distortions from bad GDP reporting have major impacts
within the financial system … With reported growth moving up and
away from economic reality, the primary significance of GDP
reporting now is as a political propaganda tool and as a
cheerleading prop for Pollyannaish analysts on Wall Street. |
The problem is that the same entity – the U.S. Government – plays
the roles of economic advocate, judge and jury. The counterfeiter
who owns the printing press (and can thus depreciate the currency at
will) also arrogates to itself the measurement of economic growth.
The heart of the problem, of course, is that the state collects
economic statistics. Sir John Cowperthwaite(1): where is your
American opposite number? The official statistics that quantify the
welfare-warfare state’s untrammelled interventionism also provide
the basis for credit agencies’ assessments of that state’s
creditworthiness. Do Uncle Sam’s statistics depict the results of
his economic policies in the best possible light? Bill Gross, the
world’s biggest bond investor, expresses little doubt: “The rating
agencies must come to understand that the federal government is
putting out works of fiction with respect to the CPI and to GDP
growth.”
A solvent entity is one that is able to pay its debts and meet its
obligations when they become due. Individuals and private sector
organisations use voluntary means to remain solvent, and coercive
sector organisations use coercive and even violent means.
Governments service their debts and other liabilities with taxes or
proceeds from the sale of assets – both of which they have
confiscated from individuals and the private sector. So if you don’t
already know it, here’s something that you absolutely must keep in
mind whilst perusing a government’s financial statements: the assets
on its balance sheet have been stolen; the valuation of assets is
arbitrary but probably vastly overstated; and the extent of
liabilities is probably hugely understated (see in particular
Michael Rozeff’s excellent "Washington’s Assets Are Our Liabilities").
Also bear in mind that Uncle Sam’s financial condition is simply
unauditable. In his
comment on 2005’s
Financial Report of the United
States Government, his internal auditor (there is, of course, no
external auditor), the Comptroller General, found – yet again! –
that his financial statements are unreliable and that his financial
controls inadequate. In particular, “A significant number of
material weaknesses related to financial systems, fundamental
recordkeeping and financial reporting, and incomplete documentation
continued to
1. hamper the federal government’s ability to reliably report a
significant portion of its assets, liabilities, costs, and other
related information;
2. affect the federal government’s ability to reliably measure the
full cost as well as the financial and non-financial performance of
certain programs and activities;
3. impair the federal government’s ability to adequately safeguard
significant assets and properly record various transactions; and
4. hinder the federal government from having reliable financial
information to operate in an economical, efficient, and effective
manner.
Because of the federal government’s inability to demonstrate the
reliability of significant portions of the U.S. Government’s
accompanying consolidated financial statements for fiscal years 2006
and 2005, principally resulting from certain material weaknesses,
and other limitations on the scope of our work, described in this
report, we are unable to, and we do not, express an opinion on such
financial statements. As a result of these limitations, readers are
cautioned that amounts reported in the consolidated financial
statements and related notes may not be reliable … |
More generally, the financial management of the federal government’s
largest agencies fails to meet requirements enacted in 1996
(see "Accounting and Accountability in Government" by Karen de
Coster). The Department of Defence is the major offender. In 2001,
its Inspector General stated “we identified $1.1 trillion [yes,
that’s a “t” and not a “b”] in department-level accounting entries
to financial data used to prepare DoD component financial statements
that were not supported by adequate audit trails or by sufficient
evidence to determine their validity. In addition, we also
identified $107 billion in department-level accounting entries to
financial data used to prepare DoD component financial statements
that were improper because the entries were illogical or did not
follow accounting principles. . . . [In conclusion], DoD did not
fully comply with the laws and regulations that had a direct and
material effect on its ability to determine financial statement
amounts” (for details, see "The Government Needs to Get Its Own
Accounting House in Order" by Robert Higgs).
Table 1: There’s (Literally!) No Accounting for the U.S.
Government |
|
Uncle Sam resembles nothing so much as an inept, hopelessly
spendthrift and disorganised man who hurriedly stuffs a shoebox full
of whatever documents and receipts he can find – and then throws the
mess into a bewildered accountant’s lap. In the private sector,
people who generate massive waste and loss face the ire of
shareholders are usually denied access to capital, often receive
pink slips and running shoes and sometimes land in gaol. In the
coercive sector, however, mismanagement is virtually never punished.
Instead, it is typically lauded and rewarded. Given its shenanigans,
the U.S. Government’s balance sheet probably overstates its assets.
It is certain that it vastly understate its liabilities.
The notes to financial statements often use soporific words but
contain startling information, and the U.S. Government’s are no
exception. These notes blandly inform the reader that the
government’s balance sheet, or what passes for one, does not reflect
intra-governmental debt holdings. Nor does it include accrued
liabilities such as the net present value of Social Security,
Medicare and other obligations. Clearly, it grossly understates the
enormity of the U.S. Government’s deficit of net worth. The 2004
Financial Report, for example, contains a section entitled
“Liabilities and Additional Responsibilities.” It brings to the
surface the staggering scope of Uncle Sam’s liabilities:
The [30 September] 2004 balance sheet shows assets of $1,397 billion
and liabilities of $9,107 billion, for a negative net position of
$7,710 billion. In addition, the Government’s responsibilities to
make future payments for social insurance and certain other programs
are not shown as liabilities according to Federal accounting
standards; however, they are measured in other contexts. These
programmatic commitments remain Federal responsibilities and as
currently structured will have a significant claim on budgetary
resources in the future … The net present value for all of the
responsibilities (for current participants over a 75-year period) is
$45,892 billion, including Medicare and Social Security payments,
pensions and benefits for Federal employees and veterans, and other
financial responsibilities. The reader needs to understand these
responsibilities to get a more complete understanding of the
Government’s finances. |
|
|