There are those that consider the federal government’s new debt as “good debt.”
Minister Flaherty, for instance, likes to spin the $125 billion he will pay for
MBS as a revenue making opportunity for Canadians. The government’s interest
costs on government bonds, after all, are less than the interest it will
probably earn from its MBS investment, so it stands to make a profit on the
spread.
Don’t be beguiled by his talk. If the big banks need $125 billion in cash that
badly, why don’t they just sell their MBS in the open market? There is, after
all, an active secondary market for CMHC MBS in which sovereign wealth funds,
hedge funds, insurance companies, and pension funds participate.
The answer is that the banks prefer to sell their MBS to the government because
they’ll inevitably get better prices than if they were to sell on the market.
Try dumping $125 billion in assets on any market and smart buyers will smell
desperation and pull back, forcing that seller to drop prices. Having the
government step in and buy saves the bank from having to pay such a penalty. If
the government ends up paying $10 billion or so more than what the market would
have born, that means the big banks are being subsided to the tune of $300 per
Canadian. That’s a few hundred of their dollars that most Canadians will never
realize has gone to the banks.
It’s not the job of the state to add to its traditional role of public service
provider that of public hedge fund, nor should Flaherty start his morning
scanning a Bloomberg terminal for securities he can buy low and sell high with
taxpayer’s money. It’s the job of individual Canadians and their advisers to
decide on what makes a good speculation or market investment. Surely they won’t
be so eager to pay the banks above market prices like Flaherty has done.
Another reason some might call our new liabilities “good debt” is that the debt-funded
purchases of MBS takes illiquid securities off the books of Canada’s big banks,
providing them with cash which they might in turn lend out to credit-starved
Canadian businesses and consumers. “It’s for the greater good,” goes the
justification.
Consider the hidden costs of this move. Going forward, Canada’s banks now have
the incentive to add whatever sorts of illiquid debts they want to their balance
sheet. After all, a government that has already spent $125 billion buying
securities from bankers at above market prices will be able to twist the
taxpayer’s arm to do it again in the future. This only promotes irresponsibility
among bankers, weakens the Canadian banking system, and in the end serves as a
hidden tax on all Canadians.
What a shame to see our debt explode higher after years of steady cuts, and to
have these funds spent on investments that provide no verifiable net benefit,
and indeed impose hidden costs on individuals and the overall banking system.
Canada’s failed effort at reducing federal government spending only shows that
governments cannot be trusted to reduce their own size. In times of crisis, they
will inevitably seize the chance to grow ever larger again.
|