|
What
Remains Seen and What Remains Unseen, 161 Years Later (Print Version) |
by Adam Allouba*
Le Québécois Libre, January
15, 2011, No 285.
Link:
http://www.quebecoislibre.org/11/110115-11.html
A recent Globe and Mail
series on dementia's toll estimated that this horrible disease costs
the Canadian economy $15 billion annually. One reader sent in the
following reply:
[W]e are contributing to the economy because of dementia, not
costing it.
We buy plane tickets or gas to visit our parents; we hire cleaning and
yard people for their homes; we pay for nurses or caregivers; we pay for
their rooms in retirement or nursing homes; we hire lawyers to draw up
powers of attorney and wills; and we pay accountants to do their taxes.
We've created a whole industry around people with dementia.
Ms. Langdon’s letter reveals two
things:
(1) She is a devoted
daughter who does her best to care for her aging parents.
(2) She is a lousy
economist.
Wait a minute – caring for people with dementia requires spending money,
which creates jobs. So isn’t Ms. Langdon just stating the obvious when
she asserts that the “dementia industry” contributes to the economy?
In fact, her economic reasoning is fatally flawed. She should not,
however, feel too much embarrassment over her mistake, since it is a
distressingly common one. Ms. Langdon’s error lies in her assumption
that the sole economic consequences of dementia are those that are
immediately visible: the nurse paid for in-home care, the attendant
hired to help feed patients, the lawyer retained to draft a power of
attorney, and so on. What she has missed are the unseen effects,
best explained by a long-dead French economic theorist.
What is Seen and What is Unseen
In 1850, Frédéric Bastiat penned his final work:
Ce qu’on voit et ce
qu’on ne voit pas. It opens with his elegantly simple parable of
the broken window: A boy accidentally breaks a man’s window. The man’s
neighbours console him with the thought that at least the child’s
mischief will provide a glazier with work. After all, “what would become
of the glaziers if panes of glass were never broken?”
Bastiat points out the crowd’s error in considering only the broken
window’s visible effect: the glazier’s work. The unseen
effect is that the money spent on the replacement window is not spent
elsewhere. Instead of a window and, say, a new pair of shoes, the man is
left only with the window. The boy’s carelessness has left the man – and
his village – poorer.
The essay applies the same reasoning to other situations in which people
often focus only on the immediate impact of economic behaviour, such as
military spending, art subsidies or public works programs. What is
seen are the jobs of the soldiers, artists or labourers and the
ripple effect of their spending. What is unseen is the economic
activity foregone by the taxpayers who finance those operations. They
would have used those funds to consume other goods and services, thereby
spending the same total amount as the state – without wasting resources
to collect, budget and spend the money.
Has the flaw in Lynda Langdon’s reasoning become apparent? Her letter
refers only to what is seen: the employment of the nurse, the
attendant, the lawyer, etc. resulting from someone’s mental illness.
What is unseen is how that money would have been spent had the
person been well – perhaps a car or a vacation. Instead of employing a
nurse, those funds could have employed an autoworker or a pilot and
instead of a sick (but well-cared for) patient, the person’s child could
have a healthy parent and the new car. Incidentally, as Bastiat
explains, even if you assume that the money would instead have been
saved and not spent, that simply makes the funds available to lend to
someone else to spend.
Modern-Day Applications
Over a century and a half later, Bastiat’s crusade against illogic has a
long way to go. The broken window fallacy and the failure to consider
what is unseen are everywhere.
Stimulus
Think back to the dark days of 2008:
plummeting
stock indices,
failing
banks and even a
collapsed national economy. From the
blackness came forth a cry:
stimulus! In February 2009,
President Obama signed a $787 billion package to jolt the economy back
to life. White House economic advisors warned that without this measure,
unemployment could peak in 2010 at
8.8%. Almost two years later, the
jobless rate stands at 9.4%,
down from a high of 9.8% in November
2010.
Perhaps, despite the mistaken projection, things would be even worse
without the stimulus. But while we can see the effect of the stimulus –
police officers hired, teachers kept on, etc. – we cannot see the
private investment that would have been made with the resources
commandeered by the state. In other words – and
as many predicted – perhaps the stimulus stimulated nothing. Maybe it just shifted spending
elsewhere, in the process wasting resources on bureaucrats to shuffle
money around. This theory is supported by a Harvard professor’s recent
analysis showing that barring truly exceptional circumstances, a dollar
of government spending produces less than a dollar’s worth
of economic
benefit.
Strategic Investments
Both
within and
without a recession, politicians extoll
“strategic investments” as a means to create jobs. Bastiat’s logic
argues that this approach is doomed to fail. Indeed, when we attempt to
see the unseen, it looks pretty ugly. A
2007 study by a pair of
Laval University economists found that government support for a new
aluminum smelter translated into an annual cost of almost $275,000 per
job created. A
2008 literature review found “near unanimity [among
economists] in the conclusion that stadiums, arenas and sports
franchises have no consistent, positive impact on jobs, income, and tax
revenues,” meaning that the abundant subsidies for such things have no
economic justification. A
2009 study of Spain’s massive renewable
energy program estimated that 2.2 jobs were destroyed for every green
job created.
But have governments re-examined their thinking? Of course not. Point
out that the state cannot magically create something from nothing and,
as Bastiat sighs, “it is said, ‘the thing is so plain it is quite
tiresome,’ and they vote as if you had proved nothing at all.”
(Un)creative Destruction
But these errors pale in comparison to the greatest folly of all: the
notion that destruction is good for the economy. As wrong as it is
counter-intuitive, the idea that refuses to die continues to receive a
great deal of air time.
The day after 9/11, Timothy Noah attempted to find a whopper of a silver
lining in a Slate piece titled, “Will Terrorism Resuscitate the
U.S. Economy?” Noah pointed out that as the US “responds to horrible
disasters by spending large sums of money […] in seeking to harm America,
terrorists will probably end up in making it more prosperous.” After
Hurricane Katrina devastated New Orleans in 2005, a federal reserve
economist
told The New York Times that “the process of
rebuilding of property contributes to an increase in output,” though he
did acknowledge that “in some sense it would be easy to argue that we
have been made worse by the hurricane.” Shortly after the massive 2010
Haitian earthquake, American studies professor Kevin Rozario
wrote
in the Wall Street Journal that “catastrophes [can] present
extraordinary opportunities to make improvements.” He called natural
disasters “engines of urban development and economic growth,” extolling
“the material benefits of destruction.”
Shaking your head at these arguments? Just one question before you pat
yourself on the back: what ended the Great Depression? If you said,
“World War II” then I’m afraid that you’re solidly in the Noah and
Rozario camp. Don’t beat yourself up, though – even Nobel laureate
economist Paul Krugman claims (in his newspaper column, mind you, not in
peer-reviewed scholarship) that
the war jolted the economy
to life.
Economist Robert Higgs has
persuasively
argued that while
mobilization ended chronic unemployment, actual prosperity only returned
after the war. But even without the empirical argument, does the idea
that war is economically beneficial make any sense? Can devoting
resources to building weapons – goods that destroy other goods
(and people) – really make us richer? What if, in order to save lives,
the Axis and Allied powers had shot their bullets into the ground,
bombed empty fields and sank their own ships at sea? And in that case,
could we trigger a boom by simply paying people to dig holes and fill
them up? Of course not, even if
John Maynard Keynes himself wrote
otherwise.
This argument is truly the mother of all broken window fallacies – and
one wonders if anyone really believes it. After all, just as no one
would tell the hero of Bastiat’s parable to smash more windows, no one
would think it makes economic sense to intentionally demolish a city,
flood a neighbourhood or start a war. Otherwise, vandalism would not be
a crime but a civic duty! As Bastiat explained, “To break, to spoil, to
waste, is not to encourage national labour; or, more briefly,
‘destruction is not profit.’” And yet Paul Krugman, among others,
insists that spending
almost
$1.2 trillion on the Iraq and
Afghan wars has boosted the US economy (most
Americans disagree).
Good news, America: a few more terrorist attacks, a couple more
invasions, and happy days are here again! If only this kind of thinking
were
limited
to satire.
But What if…
It is easy to concoct a scenario in which the broken window fallacy does
not apply (For an attempt to argue that natural disasters are good
despite the "broken window" effect, see: "How
disasters help"). A tornado destroys decrepit buildings that should
have been taken down years earlier. Public subsidies finance a new
molecule that cures cancer. And, yes, the window is replaced with a new,
energy-efficient one that recoups the installation cost.
But there is no reason to expect the government, with all its
warped incentives to act based on political expediency rather than sound
economics or science, to pick the right winners. And no sane person
would expect random devastation to coincidentally destroy only
things that already needed to be knocked down anyway. So while every
rule has an exception, the former is usually a better guide for policy
than the latter.
Bastiat’s work remains incomplete and basic economic fallacies have a
kind of immortal quality. Even so, his legacy remains a powerful one –
and now that you’ve been introduced to it, that’s one more person
inoculated against the idea that the road to riches is paved with
illness, bureaucracy or destruction.
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
*
Adam Allouba is a business lawyer based in Montreal and a graduate
of the McGill University Faculty of Law. He also holds a B.A.
and an M.A. in political science from McGill. |