The Revolution Will Be Printed |
▪
Makers: The New Industrial Revolution, by Chris
Anderson. McLelland and Stewart, 2012.
▪
The Homebrew Industrial Revolution: A Low-Overhead Manifesto,
by Kevin Carson.
Booksurge Publishing, 2010 [Free
ebook or pdf].
Cheap, easy-to-use and reliable home manufacturing tools are fast
becoming as widely available as laser printers and flatbed scanners.
What effects might this have on society?
The titles of the two books under consideration suggest that the effects
will be stupendous: nothing short of another industrial revolution. The
original industrial revolution catapulted Britain into a world-shaping
power through the cheap mass production of textiles and attendant
technologies of mechanization and steam power (not to mention
trade-friendly legislation). What some call the “second” industrial
revolution began with the Bessemer process, which lowered the price of
steel production and led to assembly line manufacturing. Some would say
digitization and robotic automation constitute yet another industrial
revolution, and now these two authors (and others) see a nascent
revolution in home and local small-batch manufacturing. But while both
have seized the same grandiose expression to discuss the subject, the
way each one imagines the outcome of the revolution could not be more
different.
The Bright Future
Chris Anderson is editor-in-chief of
Wired magazine and the
author of two previous books,
The
Long Tail: Why the Future of Business Is Selling Less of More
(2006) and
Free: The Future of a Radical Price (2009). In The
Long Tail he argued that the web makes it possible for more
producers of niche goods to find small but enthusiastic populations of
consumers, and thus survive and thrive. Whereas
mass-production/mass-distribution business models depend on satisfying a
“lowest common denominator” consumer in the “big head” of the demand
curve where sales volumes are high, niche producers occupy some spot
further along in the lower demand, low sales volume part of the curve.
That’s where the web increasingly helps specialized producers like
fringe authors and indie bands find small but dedicated groups of true
fans who will buy whatever they crank out. That book focused on the
“long tail of media.”
Anderson is also the founder of the
GeekDad blog and founder and CEO of
3D Robotics, a company that makes autopiloting systems for model planes.
It’s his experience setting up this open hardware tech business using
rapid prototyping and encouraging online discussion and modification of
his early efforts that has led him to conclude that a big shift is
coming in manufacturing in general: we’re already creating the “long
tail of things.”
The stories Anderson tells paint a vivid picture of the “maker” scene
and the serious potential for exploiting niche markets that arise when
“everyone is a designer” because prototyping software is free or
super-cheap and versatile, and easy-to-program microcontrollers are
likewise cheap and getting cheaper. And now we’re seeing the second or
third generation of true desktop manufacturing devices: small CNC
(computer numeric control) milling machines, laser cutters, 3D scanners
and 3D printers.
Domestic 3D printers in many ways epitomize the almost magical promise
of home manufacturing. These relatively simple devices move a nozzle
over a heated platform, extruding a filament of melted plastic to lay
down layer after layer of almost any shape imaginable. They follow
patterns that can be bought or found free online, or that enthusiastic
and patient users can learn to create themselves using free solid
modeling software. One popular open source model of 3D printer, the
RepRap, is specifically designed to print as many of its own components
as it can, moving incrementally closer to the day when the home
manufacturing enthusiast can reproduce his or her own workshop
from raw
materials.
Anderson does a great job of capturing the exhilaration of this
proliferating technology and the community of users who share their
designs and schematics online. He makes a plausible case that these
technologies open up huge commercial opportunities for people—in large
part because they combine with social media and the culture of
participation they encourage to drastically lower both barriers to entry
and transaction costs. It would be hard to dispute the revolutionary
potential of combining cheap and easy digital design and prototyping
systems with crowdfunding and other innovative sources of financing.
A paper recently published by a team of researchers at Michigan
Technological University described a small study in which the authors
looked at 20 consumer goods for which “equivalent” open-source printable
designs were available free online, and concluded that even if it were
only used to produce these 20 things, the printer under consideration (a
version of the RepRap) would pay for itself in under two years, and the
owners would get a significant return on investment. They printed out
things like orthotics and safety razors, which are not cheap but are not
complicated to print (with
the right designs).
Now, a team of engineering profs might not factor in the time it takes
to assemble, calibrate, and maintain an open-source 3D printer, and the
trouble involved would probably daunt
lesser mortals. But early laser printers were large, complicated and finicky too. The
undeniable momentum behind this technology will hopefully lead to
commensurate improvements in “plug-and-play”-type usability.
What about the Dark Side?
All of which is to say that I find Anderson’s enthusiasm well-justified,
and I share it. Nevertheless, there is something unsatisfying about
reading a book like Makers, and if I were to try to put my finger
on it, I would say that it’s like watching a cut of Star Wars
from which all of Darth Vader’s scenes have been removed. Writing about
the original industrial revolution, Anderson points out that the
spinning jenny and the other machines that made mass production of
clothing from cheap colonial cotton “arrived at the right time, in the
right place. Britain in the 1700s was going through an intellectual
renaissance, with a series of patent laws and policies that gave
artisans the incentive not only to invent but also to share their
inventions.” Anderson sees all “intellectual property” laws in this way:
not as state-manufactured monopolies and impediments to free market
activity, but as benign “incentives” without which nothing would ever be
invented. As if the open source software and hardware movements he
lionizes were not the obvious direct refutation of that very idea!
|
“I recommend both of these books. The one is an upbeat pep talk on some
great and probably lucrative new things, the other is a sometimes somber
but ultimately even more upbeat description of a future utopia that
would really deserve to be called the outcome of a revolution.” |
One of the current impediments to desktop 3D printing is the fact that
all the open source printer designs rely on extruding a filament of
plastic, which limits the level of fine detail they can achieve. One
reason home-printed versions of commodities that are mass produced by
injection molding are only “equivalent” is this rough-finish quality
they have. But the patents currently protecting the monopoly on laser
sintering 3D printers that can produce much finer results expire next
year, a fact that many predict will be the turning point
for desktop 3D printing. Yet if patents have ever impeded progress or caused deadweight loss in
Anderson’s world, well, it’s all been for the best. Inventors need
monopoly privileges as an incentive to come up with new things, except
when they’re on Facebook, or something.
Describing the bloody enclosures that involuntarily displaced hundreds
of thousands during the same period, Anderson writes, “Improved farming
methods, including the fencing in of pastures that avoided the 'tragedy
of the commons' problem, had a lot to do with it.” There is no doubt
that driving people off the land and into cities had “a lot to do” with
the commercial expansion of England, but if that’s a reason to gloss
over the real suffering of the people who had been managing their tragic commonses pretty stably for centuries, I’m not convinced.
That’s probably why the “revolution” described by Anderson ends up
sounding a lot like an exciting but not-very-revolutionary way to
make a little money.
There are no bad guys in Makers. Everything is up, up, up, and
you get the impression that not only will nobody be on the losing side
of the suspiciously bloodless disruptions caused by these revolutionary
“disruptive technologies,” nobody has ever really been on the losing
side at any time. In fact, change is so positive for everyone always and
everywhere that there is nobody who might, you know, resist the
revolution. A revolution without counterrevolutionaries! Huzzah!
Kevin Carson knows better. Darth Vader and all the stormtroopers haunt
the pages of The Homebrew Industrial Revolution as thoroughly as
they are absent from Makers. To begin with, Carson describes the
history of industrial revolutions in such a way as to leave no doubt why
people consider them revolutionary. Blood was spilled in the
transition from agrarian to industrial economies and again, more
significantly for Carson, in the transition from small-scale local
manufacturing to massive, centralized (what Carson characterizes as “Sloanist”)
mass-distribution production.
Size Isn’t Everything
Humanity took a “wrong turn” as far as Carson is concerned when it
allowed small, electrified local manufacturing to be crushed in favour
of the centralization deliberately promoted by state subsidies for
distribution (canals, railroads and highways, not to mention more
specific subsidies and favouritism for mass-distribution industries). By
concealing the diseconomies of scale that would have been obvious
if producers had had to pay full market price for developing
transportation networks, and by regulatory regimes that prevented
smaller local producers from competing, the state created the gigantism
of 20th century industry, along with the managerial liberalism that was
its governing ideology.
A genuine home-manufacturing revolution, as Carson sees it, would swing
the pendulum back to the missed opportunities of small-batch local
production. Unlike Anderson, Carson is happy to identify the people who
would lose in this revolution (the mass production industries) and the
villains who will fight to protect their unjustifiable power (the
regulators and obedient legislators, busy outdoing themselves in their
attempt to shore up the regimes of “intellectual property” and extend
and prolong the rents from their arbitrarily granted monopolies).
If Carson’s book benefits from the dramatic advantage of having both
good and evil represented in its pages, it suffers somewhat from
lack of focus and occasionally misplaced enthusiasm for
New-Left-sounding “community alternatives.” Carson is a left-wing market
anarchist, a senior fellow of the
Center for a Stateless
Society
and the author of two previous books, Studies in Mutualist Political
Economy and Organization Theory: a Libertarian Perspective.
As a left-libertarian, he’s anti-statist but favours market solutions
(and technologies that might help free the market) first and
foremost because they would improve the lives of poor people. I’m with
him on that—wholeheartedly—but I don’t always agree with the tone of
some of what he writes.
For instance, when he writes approvingly of the “shared machine shops”
promoted by the great left-libertarian Karl Hess in his Community
Technology (1979) and then says “[t]he same idea has appeared in the
San Francisco Bay area, albeit in a commercial rather than communitarian
form, as TechShop,” my first reaction is to ask “What’s the difference?”
It’s literally true that TechShop is a commercial venture, and Carson
plainly prefers the “communitarian” alternative, which is essentially a
cooperative or tool-sharing club. But if a commercial venture makes it
possible for makers to cheaply and reliably prototype their designs,
should they really care that they don’t own the laser-cutters
for now? Elsewhere he quotes at length and without serious criticism
a proposal for “venture communism” in which co-ownership is based on
labour not on contributions of cash or capital. Could someone
hire another person to contribute “his” labour to such a project and
thus own a piece of it? I guess probably not, but why not? At the risk
of sounding like the “vulgar libertarians” whom Carson excoriates (most
often rightly, in my opinion), I have to register my lack of enthusiasm
for the metaphysical value of labour, but I’m glad to have Carson try to
convince me otherwise. It beats listening to another whitewash of the
enclosures or anecdote about Steve Jobs.
I recommend both of these books. The one is an upbeat pep talk on some
great and probably lucrative new things, the other is a sometimes somber
but ultimately even more upbeat description of a future utopia that
would really deserve to be called the outcome of a revolution.
|
|
From the same author |
▪
Seeking Permission to Rent What's Yours: Airbnb vs.
Entrenched Interests
(no
312 – June 15, 2013)
▪
Indecision 2012, Quebec Version: Is Cleaner Government
Possible?
(no
302 – August 15, 2012)
▪
The Housing Hustle: A Review of Matthew Yglesias's The Rent
Is Too Damn High
(no
301 – June 15,
2012)
▪
Is "Capitalism" Worth Saving? A Conversation
(no
300 – May 15,
2012)
▪
Student "Strike" Is Losing Steam
(no
299 – April 15,
2012)
▪
More...
|
|
First written appearance of the
word 'liberty,' circa 2300 B.C. |
Le Québécois Libre
Promoting individual liberty, free markets and voluntary
cooperation since 1998.
|
|