A Case of Government Industrial Investment becoming Foreign
Aid |
In early 2014, a story appeared in the business media about government
investing over $1 billion in a high-tech and telecommunications company
located in Southern Ontario. Some two years earlier, the Government of
Ontario invested over $1 billion in a South Korean manufacturer of
windmills, with the possible intention of capturing a significant share
of the North American windmill market. But subsequent to the investment,
most wind farms bought windmills and related equipment from other
manufacturers. Government investment in high technology is reminiscent
of events that happened during the 1990s involving the high-tech boom
that preceded the high-tech bust.
Supporters of government investment in industry are quick to dismiss
opponents of such practices by repeating the well-worn cliché, “It’s not
the amount of money that government invests, it’s the downstream
spin-off benefits that result from that investment.” At a previous time,
this author gained access to several years of annual reports from a
government department that invested in transportation technology
development. While some pieces of technology never made it to market,
other pieces of technology entered production to compete in the market.
In at least two very high profile cases, crown corporations were the
customers.
However, a few pieces of transportation technology had to compete on the
open market and within five years of first entering production, the
market for such technology had practically disappeared. This author
sought to examine the alleged downstream benefits of the government
investment, only to discover that there was comparatively very little in
the way of long-term downstream benefits. The episodes of government
investment provided some short-term employment and some short-term
production, if such events can even be called downstream benefits.
However, the claim of downstream benefits has also been applied to the
high-tech and telecommunications industries. During the early 1980s, the
high-tech and telecommunications industries were developing quite
rapidly on mainly private sector funding. Personal and home computers
began to appear on market shelves, replacing large mainframe corporate
computers that appeared during the late 1960s and early 1970s. Sales
were good and profits were high. College and university graduates with
expertise or training in telecommunications and high technology were
assured of employment, while private investors in these sectors could
expect high rates of return. The demand for expertise in these sectors
often exceeded the supply of available domestic candidates.
Political advisors in both Canada and the USA, as well as in several
other developed nations, began to expound on the merits of government
investing in high technology and telecommunications. The chairman of the
American Federal Reserve at the time, Alan Greenspan, theorized about
creating a perpetual economic boom that the bank could sustain. Massive
amounts of government funding poured into high technology and
telecommunications companies, while educational institutions introduced
new programs to supply the demand for qualified candidates. Sector
companies also hired large numbers of highly-educated, foreign-trained
candidates.
|
“Following the high-tech meltdown, information sector, high-tech and
telecommunications business ideas were available at bargain-basement
prices, despite the billions of dollars that governments in developed
countries had pumped into those sectors during the boom years.” |
Entrepreneurs who could present new ideas in telecommunications, high
technology, or the development of information sector programs gained
easy access to government funding. Profits initially soared as new
technology and new programs became commercially available. Supporters of
increased government investment scoffed at free-market economists who
warned of an overheated high-tech market that was a bubble that could
burst. But it did burst, with massive loss of employment. Huge numbers
of small start-up companies collapsed, and even some big-name companies
declared bankruptcy. The dotcom bust and high-tech meltdown provided an
opportunity to investigate the real downstream benefits of government
investment.
Many companies that survived the high-tech sector economic shake-out
relocated part or all of their operations overseas. They urgently needed
to reduce expenses, including labour costs. High-tech expertise was
available at low cost at several overseas locations, such as China’s
Pearl Delta and the Bangalore and Hyderabad districts of India.
Following the high-tech meltdown, information sector, high-tech and
telecommunications business ideas were available at bargain-basement
prices, despite the billions of dollars that governments in developed
countries had pumped into those sectors during the boom years.
Foreign entrepreneurs and domestic entrepreneurs who moved their
operations to overseas gained easy access to technology that they could
further develop in a saner business and economic environment, literally
improving on business and technology ideas that originated in North
America. The high-tech and information sector companies located in the
developing world could access such technology and sufficiently improve
on it or change it so as to circumvent the patents. Perhaps out of $500
billion worth of government high-tech investment, foreign operations may
have gained access to about $50 billion of downstream benefits.
A
comparison can be made to government funded railway development in
mid-19th
century America, where most of the early government-funded players went
bankrupt. Later entrepreneurs could purchase railway access at bargain
prices and build competitive railway companies. Likewise, misguided
government investment in the North American high-tech, telecom and
information sectors resulted in their eventual economic collapse,
leaving the often-valuable spoils of that collapse available to overseas
interests at very low prices. Directly and indirectly, the rest of the
North American economy provided the funding that government redirected
to the high-tech, telecommunications and information sectors.
When supporters of government investment in industry raise the
importance of the downstream spin-off benefits to such investment, they
might want to re-examine economic events from the 1990s investment melee
into the high-tech, telecom and information sectors, and how much of
those downstream benefits gravitated overseas into the high-tech and
information sector districts of Bangalore, Hyderabad and the Pearl
Delta. Without a high-tech and information sector economic collapse in
North America, Asia’s high-tech and information sector may otherwise
have been much smaller and much less developed than it currently is.
|
|
From the same author |
▪
Evolving Beyond Foreign Aid
(no
321 – April 15, 2014)
▪
Private Initiative in Producing Food in Cities in the
Developing World
(no
321 – April 15, 2014)
▪
Private and Communal Property Rights in the
Developing World
(no
320 – March 15, 2014)
▪
Looming Prospects for Private and Home-Schooling in
the Developing World
(no
320 – March 15, 2014)
▪
Forcible Coercion and Socialized Medicine
(no
319 – February 15, 2014)
▪
More...
|
|
First written appearance of the
word 'liberty,' circa 2300 B.C. |
Le Québécois Libre
Promoting individual liberty, free markets and voluntary
cooperation since 1998.
|
|