Restraining Legitimate Commercial Competition in the
Maritime Transportation Sector |
In an unfettered free-market economic system, entrepreneurs need to read
the market for possible signals that suggest new business opportunities
for developing or implementing new technologies or new strategies in
order to raise productivity. Since time immemorial, humankind has
searched for ways to increase the returns from productive effort. It is
due to human ingenuity applied to the task of survival that large
settlements developed along rivers that not only provided a means of
sustenance and survival, but also a means of transportation that could
move large quantities of goods.
While people could transport goods by carrying them on their shoulders
or backs, they also learned to domesticate animals that could each carry
the same weight and volume of goods as an entire family of people. The
same animal could walk along a riverbank while pulling a small vessel
that could carry the equivalent weight and volume of goods as a whole
team of identical animals. By the 7th century, man’s
inventive spirit created a boat with a keel, rudder and moveable sail
that could actually sail a zig-zag path into a prevailing wind.
Trade between groups of people who lived at great distances from each
other depended on the ability to cheaply and efficiently move large
volumes and heavy weights across great distances, courtesy of access to
water-based transportation. By the late 19th century, a trend
had emerged, with larger ships carrying greater weight and increased
volume of cargo at lower cost per unit. This evolving trend in the
productivity of commercial transportation continues to the present day,
as is evident from the size of container ships.
Eastern Canadian Opportunity
A very large segment of the world’s trade moves in containers that each
measure 8 feet by 8 feet by 40 feet, and the largest ships can carry
over 10,000 containers between a select group of Asian and European
ports, offering shippers lower transportation costs per container than
smaller ships. While these ships can sail the newly enlarged Suez Canal,
they are too large to sail through the newly enlarged Panama Canal.
Neither can they sail into any East Coast American port for a variety of
reasons that include insufficient dock space to transfer and store
containers.
There is, however, a port located in a large and protected oceanic inlet
at Sydney, Nova Scotia, off Cabot Strait in Eastern Canada, that is
sufficiently deep to accommodate the depth of the super-sized ships and
where coastal land is readily available for development into the kind of
terminal area needed to accommodate the massive number of containers
that these ships can carry. To develop the necessary terminal capacity
for the world’s largest container ships to arrive at Halifax, in
contrast, would require massive amounts of funds to expropriate land and
demolish buildings to make space for such a terminal, compared to the
low cost available at Sydney.
|
“The essence of government
market regulation is to restrict market entry so as to
protect the commercial interests of existing players. The
very nature of such economic regulation invites insiders
from regulated industries to gain considerable influence
inside the government regulatory agencies, thereby
“capturing” them, in the economic jargon.” |
A private group previously explored the option of developing a
super-port for the world’s largest container ships at Chedabucto Bay,
near the entrance to the Strait of Canso, for the purpose of
transferring containers to smaller ships headed to several east coast
American ports plus the Port of Montreal, and during warmer weather,
ports located along the inland waterway upstream of Montreal toward the
Great Lakes. But the private group that had developed successful
maritime ports elsewhere in the world seemed to continually encounter
some unseen forms of opposition to their project in Eastern Canada.
Such opposition is the likely result of Transport Canada having
distributed large amounts of money into developing maritime terminals
and airports across Eastern Canada. The Port of Montreal is being
expanded at a cost of $350-million, including a new terminal at Varennes.
The Port of Saint John received $68 million, while Halifax International
Airport received a new $30-million runway and the Port of Sydney
received a dredge valued at $38 million. While Halifax may hope for
Ottawa to invest in its port, the recent economic downturn requires that
all levels of government curtail expenditures and allow the private
sector to invest in port development.
Follow the Money
The British comedy series Yes, Minister and its sequel Yes,
Prime Minister depicted situations where a senior bureaucrat
comically and subtly manipulated the Minister, and later the Prime
Minister, usually with his own hidden agenda or that of a political
friend. During America’s Watergate investigations and during the
Iran-Contra hearings, witnesses suggested that the investigating
government committee should “follow the money trail!” In Eastern
Canada, somebody either has something to gain or seeks to protect an
investment from competition by opposing private efforts to develop a
terminal for super-sized ships at a location such as Sydney.
It will be much cheaper for private interests to develop a terminal for
the world’s largest container ships at the Port of Sydney or even at
Saint Pierre and Miquelon than at Halifax, but developing a terminal at
either of these two locations would provide competition for
Halifax-based businesses connected to or dependent on the ship transport
industry. While using political connections to indefinitely delay
developing a terminal for mega-sized container ships at Sydney would
protect such business from competition, such action could push
development of the terminal offshore and outside of Canadian sovereign
territory, away from Transport Canada’s jurisdiction.
The essence of government market regulation is to restrict market entry
so as to protect the commercial interests of existing players. The very
nature of such economic regulation invites insiders from regulated
industries to gain considerable influence inside the government
regulatory agencies, thereby “capturing” them, in the economic jargon.
Government regulation also sustains inefficiency within regulated
industries, irrespective of whether the regulations are formal and
written or informal and unwritten. In the absence of formal market
regulation, a government agency can use a variety of means to indirectly
enact market entry control by indefinitely delaying a project.
There is a market case to be made for the operation of a terminal in
Eastern Canada that can berth the largest container ships on the ocean
and serve as the transfer point where containers are moved onto to
smaller vessels that sail to several east coast American ports as well
as ports located along the St. Lawrence waterway. While a government
agency that seeks to indefinitely delay such development may protect
commercial interests in Halifax, that agency could also be the catalyst
that drives such a terminal offshore to Bermuda, the Azores, or Saint
Pierre and Miquelon.
|
|
From the same author |
▪
Residential Schools and Governmental Failure
(no
333 – June 15, 2015)
▪
Ontario Sex-Ed Curriculum Protests & Government
Infallibility
(no
332 – May 15, 2015)
▪
Water as State Property
(no
332 – May 15, 2015)
▪
Free Market Trade and Border Towns
(no
330 – March 15, 2015)
▪
Growing Concerns about Sexual Violence on Campus
(no
329 – February 15, 2015)
▪
Alberta Challenges Home-Schooling Families
(no
329 – February 15, 2015)
▪
More...
|
|
First written appearance of the
word 'liberty,' circa 2300 B.C. |
Le Québécois Libre
Promoting individual liberty, free markets and voluntary
cooperation since 1998.
|
|