Beyond the Science: The Layperson's Guide to Climate Change |
As the coverage of the recently-concluded United Nations Climate Change
Conference
reminds us,
there may be no more controversial issue today than climate change. On
the one side are those for whom it is the great moral imperative of our
time to do everything possible to stop the putative warming of our
planet, failing which the human race itself is at risk. On the other are
those for whom the idea is history’s greatest hoax, a tale woven by
authoritarian charlatans who crave money and power to build an
eco-fascist dystopia.
This piece is pointedly not about the science of climate
change, for the excellent reason that I am no better placed to express
such an opinion than I am to perform heart surgery or to design a
suspension bridge. Like most of us, I have neither the time to review
the relevant scientific literature nor the expertise to understand it
even if I tried. Instead, this piece is about how to think about climate
change for those of us who are unequipped to hold an informed,
scientifically-grounded opinion. An inability to understand the
underlying science does not preclude one from contributing to the debate
over climate change in other ways.
First, the reason that climate change matters is that its potential
consequences—flooding, drought, extreme weather, etc.—are a problem for
human beings. Unlike nuclear war, an asteroid strike, and certain other
potential threats to our planet, climate change poses no danger to life
itself. Indeed, a warming planet should benefit many
non-human species.
And every inch of lost coastline is new habitat for marine animals. So
unless you believe for some reason that the interests of polar bears are
more urgent than those of jellyfish, the only reason to care about
climate change is that you believe that it will harm human beings.
Second, the science of climate change is just that: science, not
politics, not economics. It is an
article of faith
among leftists that action on climate change is urgent, while for most
conservatives and libertarians the issue can be safely ignored. These
are opinions not on climate science but on the role of government. Only
scientists can answer the basic questions necessary to diagnose the
problem: Is the planet’s climate changing? If so, why and what
consequences might result and how likely are each of them? And what
actions would help mitigate the negative effects?
Third, scientists operate by formulating hypotheses and then
conducting experiments to test them. They analyse the resulting data and
submit their conclusions to their peers for review before publication.
This mechanism helps keep scientific research honest and grounded in
best practices. Like any process, it is imperfect and has been known
to
fail.
But the best evidence that it works is the world around us, in which
planes fly through the air, diseases are cured and buildings stay up.
People can be conned, but reality is an unforgiving judge. And so if
there is indeed a
97% consensus
in the literature that the climate is changing and that human activity
is the cause, it is unthinkable that the entire thing could simply be a
fraud. Of course, the claim that such a consensus exists may itself be
incorrect,
but the best conclusions of scientists on a given issue cannot
responsibly be dismissed as fraudulent.
Fourth, while a genuine scientific consensus cannot be fraudulent,
it can be wrong. Experts are only as good as the current state of
knowledge, and
new research
reminds us that even if “everyone” knows something, “everyone” is
sometimes wrong. A scientific consensus tells us that to the best of our
knowledge, something is true. But the phrase “to the best of our
knowledge” cannot simply be dismissed as though it were meaningless.
|
“Unless you believe for some
reason that the interests of polar bears are more urgent
than those of jellyfish, the only reason to care about
climate change is that you believe that it will harm human
beings.” |
Fifth, any actions that would mitigate climate change would entail a
cost that human beings would have to bear. The most likely prescription,
a significant reduction in the emission of greenhouse gases caused by
the consumption of fossil fuels, would be anything but cost-free. When
it developed the technology to use fossil fuels, the human race gained
access to
abundant energy
that, over the past century or so, has powered the greatest increase in
wealth (and therefore the greatest reduction in poverty) in the history
of our species. Until we develop another technology that is cheaper or
otherwise better, curbing our use of fossil fuels would cripple our
ability to create wealth and harm us all, particularly the poorest.
Sixth, once scientists have given us their best answers to the
questions before them (recognizing that no such answer is ever
definitive), the matter of what is to be done requires an economic
analysis. This is not an argument that the economy is more
important than the environment. It is an observation that, given that
the point of combatting climate change is improving human quality of
life and it can only be combatted at a cost, once we know whether there
is a problem, its size and what can be done about it, then economic
analysis—an examination of trade-offs—is the only way to sensibly
determine the optimal course of action.
Seventh, the best economic analysis may determine that the proposed
solution would be costlier than even the worst possible consequences.
For example, avoiding a rise in the seas that would flood an area
inhabited by 700 million people may require consigning several billion
people to perpetual poverty by depriving them of access to the cheap
energy granted by fossil fuels. It might make more sense to build
seawalls or otherwise help those 700 million mitigate the negative
effects of rising waters. Of course, a meaningful economic analysis
would need to take into account myriad factors such as the rate of
change (does the flooding occur over a decade or a century?),
alternative energy sources (how viable are solar or nuclear power?) and
innumerable other considerations. But it is possible that doing nothing
may be the most sensible course of action.
Eighth, and most importantly, if the conclusion is that action
should be taken, only a voluntary approach can hope to produce the
desired result because state action is invariably governed not by
science but by politics. This phenomenon has more illustrations than
there are stars in the cosmos, but for our purposes let’s recall the
Liberal Party’s
Green Shift
proposal during the 2008 federal election.
If climate change is real, manmade, and a serious threat, then the
policy’s logic was irreproachable. Greenhouse gas emissions constitute a
negative externality,
since they warm the planet, the cost of which is mostly borne by people
other than the polluter. The proposed solution was to tax carbon
emissions at $10 per ton (eventually rising to $40), thereby
transferring that cost back to the emitter. In economic terms, this is a
way to internalize the externality.
The problem is that politics got in the way. For one, the Liberals’
platform did not even attempt to explain how the amount of the tax was
calculated. Properly done, the amount of the tax would be a function of
the degree to which emissions need to be reduced and the price
sensitivity of polluters—in sum, a determination of what level of
emissions are acceptable and how high the tax needs to be to get there.
If the Liberals conducted any such analysis, their platform was silent
on it. More likely, the figures seem to have been determined based on
what the Liberals thought that Canadians would be willing to accept
rather than scientific considerations.
Another problem was the perception that the policy would be, as the
Conservative Party dubbed it, a “tax on everything.”
The Liberals had clearly anticipated this line of attack and asserted
that the Green Shift would be revenue neutral: The carbon levy would be
accompanied by large cuts in personal and corporate taxes. As a result,
Ottawa’s overall revenues would remain unchanged. But when it became
clear that the policy was a tough sell, party leader Stéphane Dion
announced that certain groups whose activities are directly reliant on
fossil fuels—such as farmers, truckers and fishermen—would benefit from
a
tax break
to offset the higher cost of carbon. The policy would be tailored so as
not to alienate interest groups that the Liberals wished to keep onside.
In other words, politics would trump sound policy. However good it might
have been in theory, the Green Shift was always doomed to fail in
practice.
People who are ordered to behave in a certain way generally view it
as an imposition to be worked around. Conversely, those who freely
accept to do something will normally do it in good faith. If we need to
revolutionize our ways, any top-down fix imposed by the state will
produce the distorted incentives, unintended consequences and other
problems associated with any government policy. A bottom-up, grassroots
approach driven by a genuine, widespread desire to change individual
behaviour is much more likely to succeed. And since long-term
environmental concerns are an unaffordable luxury for those worried
about short-term survival, that desire is more likely to arise in people
made wealthy by free markets. If climate change does pose a serious
problem, then liberty offers the best chance at both finding and
implementing the necessary solution.
|
|
From the same author |
▪
Harper's Decade: The Social Legacy
(no
336 – November 15, 2015)
▪
Harper's Decade: The Economic Legacy
(no
336 – November 15, 2015)
▪
The Canadian Election: Looking on the Bright Side
(or, Putting Lipstick on a Pig)
(no
335 – October 15, 2015)
▪
I Don't Agree with His Bart-Killing Policy, but I Do
Approve of His Selma-Killing Policy
(no
334 – Sept. 15, 2015)
▪
Thank You, Edward Snowden
(no
333 – June 15, 2015)
▪
More...
|
|
First written appearance of the
word 'liberty,' circa 2300 B.C. |
Le Québécois Libre
Promoting individual liberty, free markets and voluntary
cooperation since 1998.
|
|